Growth, money and credit: The case for a cut gets stronger

The updates to the money supply and bank credit statistics (to July 2011) and GDP numbers (second quarter 2011) indicate that while the economy grew in recent months, it was at a declining rate. As is the inconvenient practice in SA, the GDP output and income numbers arrive unaccompanied by the other side of the national income identity, the aggregate expenditure estimates. And given that the current state of the SA economy can be attributed to little demand rather than to limits on the supply side of the economy, it is particularly inconvenient not to have details and explanations about the state of aggregate demand in the economy.

The GDP statistics indicated that activity closely connected to demands from households grew satisfactorily in the second quarter. Government consumption spending accounting for 15.9% of the economy (on employment benefits and consumables such as stationery and travel expenses etc) grew by a robust 5.7% (seasonally adjusted and annualized, as are all rates in this discussion, unless otherwise stated) in the quarter, while activity in the wholesale, retail and transport sectors (13.7% of GDP) grew by 4.1%. Activity in the very important financial and associated business service sectors (21% of GDP), grew by a more pedestrian 2.9%.

The laggards were primary production: agriculture (3.3% of GDP) and mining (7.2% of GDP) that declined at a 7.8% rate in the quarter with mining output falling at a 4.2% rate in the quarter. Industrial output declined at a seasonally adjusted 5.2% annual rate while manufacturing output, with only a 12.7% share of GDP, declined at a disturbing 7% rate. It should be appreciated that mining volumes and mining revenues can tell a very different tale, as they did in this quarter, when mining sales and profits were buoyed by rising prices, while the volume of output that could be exported was seriously constrained by railway capacity. As an indication of an improved top line for SA business the gross operating (profit) surpluses of business grew from R315bn in the first quarter to R346bn in the second. This surplus in money of the day was 11% greater than a year before. Employees took home an extra R7bn in the second quarter, representing an increase of 10%.

Thus the share of operating surpluses in gross value added continued to rise, to 48% while employees share was 44%, with the balance of value added attributed to taxes on output. South African business continues to become more profitable hiring fewer, better paid employees, whose share in value added has declined (despite higher real remuneration). Productivity therefore must have increased, aided by less expensive capital (which was freely available with a lower risk premium).

Money and credit: The housing factor

The underlying weakness in aggregate domestic demand is confirmed by the direction of money and credit supplies. As we show below the growth in the money supply broadly defined (M3) has picked up from mid recession growth rates of a year before. But the annual growth rates may well have stalled about the 5%-6% year on year rate. The private credit extended by the banks (approximately the other asset side of the balance sheets of banks) indicates a similar picture of growth, stabilizing at the 5% to 6% rate. The weakest aspect of bank lending, as may be seen, is mortgage lending. Growth in mortgage lending (while positive) appears to be declining to a roughly 3% year on year rate. This does not speak well of the housing market and the demand for extra building and renovation activity. Without a recovery in the housing market the top lines of the banks, about 50% dependent on mortgage lending, is unlikely to improve.

On the evidence of a slowing economy and growth in money supply and credit (which is barely keeping up with inflation), the case for lower interest rates to stimulate demand would seem uncontestable. The money market has begun to factor in the possibility of a cut in short term interest rates by the first quarter of next year. The odds of a 50bps cut in the repo rate are still below evens (about a 35% probability).

Unless the outlook for the domestic and global economies improves and money supply and credit growth pick up soon, these probabilities of a cut in rates will rise. Hindsight confirms what we have long argued, that interest rate settings in SA have been too high for too long for the sake of the economy – without any obvious influence on the exchange rate or the inflation outlook.

Growth in money supply
Growth in mortgage lending

The Eurozone crisis: Mme Lagarde’s three steps to salvation

Christine Lagarde, now head of the IMF and recently Minister of Finance in the Sakorzy government, told the Jackson Hole Conference of central bankers on Saturday of the three key steps that Europe should take to work its way out of crisis:

Step 1 she recommended, was to “… sustain sovereign finances – more fiscal action and more financing….” and cautioned that this did not require “…. drastic upfront belt-tightening—if countries address long-term fiscal risks like rising pension costs or healthcare spending, they will have more space in the short run to support growth and jobs. But without a credible financing path, fiscal adjustment will be doomed to fail. After all, deciding on a deficit path is one thing, getting the money to finance it is another. Sufficient financing can come from the private or official sector—including continued support from the ECB, with full backup of the euro area members.”

Step 2 was more urgent and perhaps more controversial.

That is to say, European banks “….need urgent recapitalization. They must be strong enough to withstand the risks of sovereigns and weak growth. This is key to cutting the chains of contagion. ……The most efficient solution would be mandatory substantial recapitalization—seeking private resources first, but using public funds if necessary. One option would be to mobilize EFSF or other European-wide funding to recapitalize banks directly, which would avoid placing even greater burdens on vulnerable sovereigns…..”

European banks face a large difficulty that is not of their own making. Holding debt issued by their own sovereigns has always been regarded as the safest way for banks to lend out the cash they take in as deposits. Indeed they are often required by regulators to hold significant quantities of securities issued by the government and its agencies. Holding the debt issued by foreign governments has been optional for banks and some governments are more risky than others and pay higher interest rates accordingly. European banks currently own 45% of all European Government debt: some good, some bad and some downright ugly.

The notion that members of the Euro monetary union could default on their debts was unthinkable until recently. Ordinarily governments escape default on debt denominated in their own currency by requiring their central banks to monetize their debt.

The problem when a government is printing cash to fund its expenditure is potential inflation, not default. But, in the terms of the European Monetary Union, only the European Central Bank (ECB) can issue more euros. In the absence of a fiscal union to accompany a monetary union, such powers to print money to resolve a banking crisis have been compromised by national rather European interests. The fiscally sound members of the monetary union, mostly located in Northern Europe, are reluctant to subsidise the fiscally irresponsible members of the union to the south of them. For the central bank to treat all the government bonds issued by all European governments as having the same face value when exchanged for ECB deposits would mean a subsidy to the profligate.

In reality the ECB has been accepting government securities of all kinds without distinction offered to it by all European banks in exchange for cash at its discount or repurchase window. It has pumped in large supplies of cash to European banks who have demanded cash from the ECB, accompanied by collateral in the form of Euro government debt. Such action is within its discretionary powers. Had it not lent so freely Europe would have suffered a run on all its banks and a liquidity crisis. The decline in the yields on Italian and Spanish government bonds has revealed the success these ECB purchases have had in calming the Euro bond market.

That there is no liquidity crisis in Europe is identified by the increase in the cash held by European banks well in excess of their legal requirements to hold cash. As we show below European banks are following the example of the US counterparts in building up their cash reserves at the expense of their lending.

European Banks - Actual and excess cash reserves
European Banks - Actual and excess cash reserves

What the ECB cannot do of its own volition is the equivalent of the QE2 or TARP (Troubled Assets Recovery Program) activities conducted by the US Fed and the US Treasury. That is, they cannot go directly into the markets and offer to buy government securities and mortgage backed securities on a large scale to inject liquidity and (more important in the case of TARP) to inject fresh capital into the banks and other financial institutions.

As Mme Legarde has identified, it is capital rather than cash that the European banks are short of. Such a need to raise more capital is reflected by the lower values attached to the shares of European banks. European banks are trading at about half the value of the assets on their books. Their books have an important part made up of suspect government securities which may not have been written down to reflect market realities; while the scope for increasing the size of their books is impaired by the weak Euro economies. This decline in the equity market value of the banks makes them more vulnerable and less able to raise meaningful amounts of capital from their shareholders.

They need the equivalent of a Warren Buffett to come to their rescue, as he did with Bank of America. Failing this shareholders may have no choice but to subscribe to deeply discounted rights issues offered by banks that might otherwise go out of business. The further alternative is of course to rely on governments to subscribe to the capital of banks. The banks may hope that capital provided by governments is a temporary provision (as it has proved to be in the US where banks have paid back the government with a profit) and also not accompanied by too much political interference in the business of banking.

This then brings the discussion to step 3, which Lagarde believes Europe will have to take if it is to enjoy a full recovery and retain its monetary and banking systems in more or less their present form.

To quote her: “Europe needs a common vision for its future. The current economic turmoil has exposed some serious flaws in the architecture of the eurozone, flaws that threaten the sustainability of the entire project. In such an atmosphere, there is no room for ambivalence about its future direction. An unclear or confused message will add to market uncertainty and magnify the eurozone’s economic tensions. So Europe must recommit credibly to a common vision, and it needs to be built on solid foundations—including, for example, fiscal rules that actually work.”

The European monetary union is being sustained by the ability of the ECB to print money to keep its banks and governments afloat. The crisis is being overcome this way. Any permanent solution to the issues Europe faces requires fiscal stability and a fiscal union that effectively limits government spending in Europe to what European taxpayers can support. The hope for Europe is that fiscal responsibility can only be realized by governments spending less – especially in ways that discourage the work, savings and enterprise of its citizens. The limits to the taxes European governments can collect has long been exceeded, as its fiscal crisis makes clear.

The interest rate outlook for SA has changed dramatically

There have been dramatic developments on the SA interest rate front over the past two weeks. The money market, having confidently predicted an increase in short term rates this year or early next year, now very confidently expects short term interest rates to stay on hold for 12 months or more. The figures below tell the story of how the prediction of slower global growth has influenced the outlook for the SA economy and so interest rates. The case for lower interest rates in SA, one we have made for some time, has become even stronger and might in turn become reflected in a negatively sloped rather than flat short term yield curve.

The short term yield curve as implied by three month Forward Rate Agreements
Probability of a hike

The long term yield curve has also flattened significantly in response to the outlook for lower short term rates. The slope of the long term yield is still positive, indicating that short rates are expected to rise rather than fall in due course. However the one year benchmark interest rate is now only expected to move above 7% in three years’ time. As may be seen in the charts below, the one year rate is now expected to flatten out below the 9% rate in about six years.

Zero Coupon Yield Curve
Implied One Year Yield

The question then arises as to what might cause the yield curve to flatten or steepen in the year to come. Were the global economy to grow faster than is now expected, this surely would be associated with strength in emerging market equities and therefore also in the rand. The outlook for SA growth would improve in these circumstances while the outlook for inflation (given rand strength) would not deteriorate. The yield curve might then shift lower at the longer end and there would be downward market pressure on short rates (which the Reserve Bank might choose to resist).

Were the outlook for the global economy to deteriorate further, there would be additional downward pressure on short rates. The yield curve might well turn negative, should short term rates be expected to decline given slower growth. However the rand is unlikely to be well supported in such circumstances and so the outlook for inflation may not improve if we were to see a combination of a weaker rand and lower global commodity prices, including a lower oil price. These opposing forces (slower global growth plus a weaker rand) will restrain any fall in inflation or inflation expected over the long run and so limit the fall in long term rates. A flat to negatively sloped yield curve might then prevail until the outlook for the global and SA economy improved.

Clearly the combination of faster global growth without more inflation (shielded by a stronger rand) is much to be preferred. However there is one great consolation, should the global economy not help the SA economy along: the danger of an increase in short term rates has passed. The money market is confirming this and the Reserve Bank will indicate as much in due course.

Interest rates: Sombre is good

A sombre outlook for the domestic and the global economy was presented yesterday by Reserve Bank governor Gill Marcus, helping the case for leaving rates unchanged, as had been confidently expected. The case for higher rates any time soon was weakened by the arguments presented in the MPC statement and in the Q&A session that followed. The opportunity to lower rates was not considered, as we were informed, though perhaps it should have been. Cost push pressures on inflation were again emphasized in the statement – and second round effects of higher inflation expected (on inflation itself) were regarded as not in evidence. Inflationary expectations, as measured for the Bank, were reported as stable to lower.

The Reserve Bank expects the small breach of the upper 6% band of the inflation targets by the first quarter of 2012 but is of the view that this breach will be very temporary and therefore no reason in itself to raise the repo rate. Base effects are pushing inflation higher in the second half of 2011 and will reverse in 2012. The key to the inflation target remains the foreign exchange value of the rand and this is proving very helpful and we think will continue to be so – to the point that the Reserve Bank is over- rather than underestimating inflation.

Prominent reference was made in the statement and in the Q&A to the “core” rate of inflation, that is inflation excluding food and energy prices, which is of the order of just over 3%. An inflation target set in terms of core inflation rather than headline inflation is preferred by many of the leading authorities on inflation targeting and the Reserve Bank may well be moving in that direction. This represents an important and welcome departure from previous Governor Mboweni’s practice and rhetoric, who was determined to allow no such distinctions or escape clauses for meeting the inflation targets. This different mindset reinforces our argument for and prediction of low interest rates for longer. Moreover it raises the likelihood of generally more stable short term interest rates in the future which would be very helpful for SA business and its customers.

Closing the gap

At the Q&A, so called output gaps received interesting attention, that is the gap between potential GDP and actual levels of output. This gap is judged still to be open but is said to be closing with current growth rates ahead of potential growth. Potential output growth this year was indicated as only 3.5% with second half growth slowing down rather than picking up. This represents a very pessimistic view of SA’s long term growth potential and is not one consistent with much growth in employment and the government objectives for employment growth.

This Reserve Bank sense of potential growth is presumably derived from a limited estimate of SA’s ability to attract foreign capital, equivalent by definition to the sustainable size of the current account deficit – both usually measured as a share of GDP. We have argued that such pessimism may be unjustified and that growth can lead capital inflows that finance and sustain growth. In other words, grow faster to improve the returns on capital invested, and the capital from global sources will be forthcoming. There is a potential virtuous circle for SA that was in evidence between 2003 and 2007 (grow faster- attract more capital – sustain the value of the rand – holds down inflation and interest rates). But expressing faith or confidence in such possibilities of faster growth with less inflation aided by foreign capital, is not behaviour expected of inflation vigilant central bankers.

GDP growth is expected by the Reserve Bank to be about 3.7% in 2011 and 3.9% in 2012, increasing to 4.4% in 2013. When the presumed output gap is finally closed (on these assumptions) late in 2012 the case for raising rates will then be more confidently made. Pressures on global food inflation are however thought by the MPC to have peaked. The MPC outlook is for inflation at the upper band 6% rate by year end and is expected to remain above this 6% upper band for the inflation target until the second quarter of 2012 and receding thereafter.

Something in reserve …

Had we been at the Q&A session we would have asked the Governor and her bench of advisors why the Reserve Bank thinks it still useful to add to its already abundant supply of foreign exchange reserves. These are large enough for any conceivable emergency that might shock the SA balance of payments. The governor indicated her own confusion about the forces that drive the rand. Clearly Reserve Bank interventions in the currency market have had no predictable influence on the rand. The realised strength of the rand has made such intervention very expensive for the SA taxpayer on whose behalf the Treasury borrows rands at 6% to 8%, to offset the impact of dollar purchases on the money supply, for the Reserve Bank to invest in US dollars and Euros that return around 2% at best. It has been an expensive and futile exercise in trying to resist market forces.

We might suggest that the behaviour of the rand is not that mysterious and will continue to take its cue from global risk appetite, well reflected in emerging equity and bond markets. The well understood rand does not make it easier to predict. This remains the essential problem for monetary policy in SA, which is to hold inflation down not for its own sake but to encourage long term economic growth (lest we forget the purpose of inflation targeting).

To view the graphs and tables referred to in the article, see Daily Ideas in the Daily View: Daily View 22 July

Credit and housing markets: Still no case for higher rates

The credit and money supply numbers for April 2011 indicate that the pace of money supply and credit growth, especially growth in mortgages, pedestrian before, is slowing down gradually, rather than accelerating. The growth trends in M3, the broadest definition of the money supply including almost all deposits issued by the banks, is most clearly pointing lower.

It is demands for bank credit that lead the money supply process in SA. As the banks lend more, the Reserve Bank accommodates the banks with additional cash- that is cash reserves – at the prevailing repo rate. More credit demanded leading to more money supplied is the modus operandi of the SA Reserve Bank. The demands for credit lead the supply of cash and more broadly defined money. A large proportion of SA bank lending is on mortgage and mortgage demands remain especially tepid as we also show below.

Growth in mortgage lending follows house price inflation, as we show below, where it may be seen that the price of the average home is now unchanged compared with a year ago. A housing boom leads to a credit boom and rapid growth in the money supply as it did between 2003 and 2008 – and when the housing boom slows down, so does money supply growth as it has recently. Interest rate settings have proved incapable of effectively moderating the credit and money supply cycles in SA.

Until the housing market picks up the growth in bank lending will remain subdued. The recovery in the housing market has lagged behind the recovery in the economy. It will take further growth in formal sector employment to revive the housing market.

Lower interest rates on mortgage loans, applied much earlier in the slow down, might have helped moderate the contraction in the credit and money cycles, but these now appear most unlikely given the recent uptick in inflation. The credit and money supply numbers should however help dissuade the Reserve Bank from raising interest rates.

There is clearly no money or credit supply growth reason for raising interest rates, nor any excess demands for houses or anything else that would need to be restrained by higher interest rates. Indeed the opposite, lower rates, would still appear appropriate, given the state of the economy and in particular the state of the housing market and the construction industry that is an important employer of labour.

We show below the recent collapse in the cycle of buildings completed. We show how building plans passed have led the building industry lower. The indication is that he planning cycle has at best bottomed out, offering only the hope that construction activity will soon also bottom out and recover.

It is of interest to note that house prices lead not only mortgage demands but also building plans passed. It takes higher house prices to encourage construction activity.

The weak state of the credit and housing markets, that are inextricably bound together, makes the case for lower rather than higher interest rates. The Reserve Bank appears understandably reluctant to raise interest rates in the circumstances. The currently higher inflation rate is of the supply side, cost push administered price variety over which monetary policy has no influence and if it persists will weaken demand further.

Furthermore, as we have mentioned before, we have found no evidence of second round effects of inflation, that is, more inflation that leads to more inflation expected that leads in turn to more actual inflation. Fighting these feared second round effects have become an argument for higher interest rates, regardless of their negative effect on economic activity. Such arguments should be ignored and the SA public and market place made to understand why.

To view the graphs and tables referred to in the article, see Daily Ideas in todays Daily View: Daily View 1 June: Credit and housing markets: Still no case for higher rates

The rand: Foundations still to be laid

This past month has not been a particularly good one for the rand. The rand lost about 7% against the Aussie dollar in May 2011 to date, while losing less about three per cent Vs the Brazilian real and the US dollar.

We have long watched the relationship between the rand and the Aussie dollar for signs of South African specific risks influencing the value of the rand rather than commodity prices that are common to both currencies. A combination of commodity price strength and rand weakness is a heady one for investors in Resource companies, quoted in rands, on the JSE.

However the current modest rand weakness would appear to have more to do with favourable Australian, rather than less favourable South African specifics. This view is supported by the better performance of the rand against the US dollar and the Brazilian currency.

The rand is more than a commodity currency. It is also very much an emerging market currency and actively traded as a proxy for other less liquid emerging market currencies. The beat to which the rand is moving this month has been day to day volatility on emerging equity markets. The rand has been getting weaker or stronger as emerging equity markets have been going down or up in a highly synchronised way. And the JSE remains a highly representative emerging equity market.

It would appear that it is very much emerging market business as usual in the market for rands. If we run a model that uses the EM equity market Index to explain the rand/US dollar exchange rate using daily data since January 2008, the rand is trading almost exactly as the model predicts.

In the large market for the rand, with daily turnover of about US$20bn making it about the tenth largest foreign exchange market, three quarters of the transactions reported to the SA Reserve Bank are conducted between third parties with no direct link to SA foreign trade or capital movements. They trade the rand because they can trade the rand to hedge emerging market exposures.

The notion that the SA Reserve Bank could intervene effectively in such a market to move the exchange value of the rand in some preferred direction would seem a false premise. The Reserve Bank can buy foreign currency in this market to add to its reserves, as it has been doing, but such interventions could not easily be seen as market moving. The value of the rand continues to be dominated by global forces, particularly those that influence the outlook for the global economy and so emerging equity and bond markets. South African specifics seem to have had little influence on the exchange value of the rand in recent years and we expect global forces to continue to dominate the rand exchange rates.

The rand began the year at R6.61 per US dollar. It lost about 10% of this value by early February 2011 and then reclaimed its beginning of the year value in late April 2011. It has by now lost about 4% of its January 2011 value against the US dollar this year, while the Aussie and the real are about three percent stronger than they were at the beginning of the year.

While the volatility in the market for rands this year may be regarded as moderate by its own standards, the still unusual volatility in the rand must remain of concern to the authorities in SA. Without rand stability, predicting inflation and interest rates more than six months ahead with any degree of accuracy or confidence, remains a near impossible task. The foundations for genuinely stabilising monetary policy and interest rate settings in the form of a stable and predictable rand have still to be laid.

To view the graphs and tables referred to in the article, see Daily Ideas in todays Daily View:

Daily View 27 May: The rand: Foundations still to be laid

After the MPC: Interest rate expectations and the rand

The money market has raised the probability of an early increase in short term interest rates (in three months’ time) following the meeting of the Reserve Bank’s Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) on Thursday that maintained the repo rate at 5.5%. The short term three month Forward Rate Agreement curve (FRA) of the banks moved higher by between 10 and 30bps across the range of forward rates beyond the next three months late last week.

Interest rates expected over the longer term, beyond four years, have remained unaffected. The zero coupon yield curve implies that the one year government bond rate, currently around 6% per annum, will rise consistently to a level of about 9% in four years’ time and then stabilise at this level.

These expectations remain consistent with inflation compensation priced into the bond market in the form of the yield gap between conventional RSA bond yields and their inflation linked alternatives. This gap remains consistently above 6% regardless of the rate of inflation.

Our own interpretation of the MPC statement and the press conference is that the Governor and the MPC would be extremely reluctant to take any interest rate action before the economy has regained its potential growth, which it is still some way from attaining. However further increases in fuel and food prices and the headline inflation rate might force them in this direction for fear of second round effects on inflation itself. In other words, more inflation expected would lead in turn to still more inflation.

We have found comprehensive evidence that inflation in SA does to a small degree influence inflation expected, as measured for the Reserve Bank by surveys conducted by the Stellenbosch Bureau of Economic Research for business, trade unions and financial institutions. However, the reverse has not been true, although the Reserve Bank seems to believe otherwise.

Moreover it is clearly concerned to preserve its inflation fighting credentials even if this should mean having to raise rates. This is so even when it is clear that the inflation it is attacking is not under its control and when higher interest rates might lead to slower growth and a wider gap between actual and potential output and employment. The striking feature of inflation expectations in SA is just how stable they have been and how they remain above the inflation target band of 3% to 6%.

As we indicated in our first reactions to the MPC statement, the outlook for interest rates in SA will depend primarily (and unfortunately) on the rand price of oil and the continued upward direction of administered prices and not on the state of the economy that might be intolerant of higher interest rates. There should be a better way of running monetary policy in SA with more sensitivity to the state of the domestic economy and with the media and the financial markets well able to understand that a shock to the inflation rate does not imply permanently higher inflation. Keeping interest rates on hold in such circumstances when demand pressures are subdued does not mean being soft on inflation. This better way is indicated by the inflation targeting mandate itself, which does not demand adherence to inflation targets regardless of the causes of inflation and the consequences of higher interest rates for the economy, as is indicated explicitly and clearly in Paragraph 4 of the Mandate.

The rand has however weakened in recent days despite an earlier expected increase in interest rates. This again confirms that the influence of movements in interest rates on the value of the rand is not easily predicted. As we show below the rand lost about 4% of its trade weighted value last week.

Perhaps the market is being influenced to a degree by the unknown outcomes of the municipal elections in SA on Wednesday, which have become a test of the national government and its competence to govern. A small additional protest vote would probably be welcome as an incentive for the government to improve its delivery. An unexpectedly large vote for the opposition might be regarded as a serious longer term threat to the powers that be, and would perhaps have unpredictable outcomes for the ruling party, its leadership and its policies. As we know markets do not appreciate uncertainty.

To view the graphs and tables referred to in the article, see Daily Ideas in todays Daily View:
Daily View 16 May: After the MPC: Interest rate expectations and the rand

Think beyond just inflation

The Reserve Bank, as expected, kept its repo rate steady despite raising its estimate of inflation to come, now seeing inflation as marginally above 6% by year end. However it also predicted to return to within the band in 2012. The explanation of this increase was “cost push” rather than demand forces, therefore not justifying higher interest rates (in the absence of “second round effects”).

Second round effects are defined as higher inflation caused by more inflation expected. This, according to the theory of monetary policy, might demand higher interest rates to fight inflation expected, even if this depressed the economy. This dilemma – the unhappy trade off between inflation and economic activity – is something the MPC would naturally prefer to avoid. The big question is will it continue to do so?

Our own work has unambiguously identified the absence of second round effects. Inflation in SA has influenced inflation expected, not the other way round. Thus we do not expect second round effects to show up. But the inflation outlook remains particularly uncertain given the uncertainty about the direction of the US dollar and the oil price in particular. And if the inflation rate rises and is expected to stay above the upper band of 6% this policy dilemma will become more acute, with or without measurable second round effects.

We notice again and welcome the willingness of the Reserve Bank to think beyond actual inflation to the causes of inflation and the recognition that monetary policy must also bear the outlook for economic and employment growth in mind. The revised mandate for the Reserve Bank makes this very clear.

It should be pointed out though that, in answer to a question, this point about a broader focus than a focus on inflation only was not made by the governor. The governor, like all governors of central banks, would hate to be interpreted as being soft on inflation, particularly when inflation is expected to rise above the target band and even when there is very good reason to ignore “cost push” pressures. And so anti-inflationary vigilance must always be stressed by central bankers, for fear that their lack of monetary action being misinterpreted as evidence of a lack of anti-inflationary conviction by the market place.

However, as was made clear by the MPC, the state of the economy does not support higher interest rates. As we have previously indicated the Reserve Bank is also of the view that economic activity may have decelerated rather than accelerated recently. And so, until the economy does pick up significant momentum, accompanied by significantly faster growth in bank credit the Reserve Bank will prefer to keep interest rates on hold. Yet it might feel obliged to raise rates despite the weakness of aggregate demand (wrongly in our view) should the actual inflation outlook deteriorate even if such higher inflation is beyond the control of the Bank itself.

The oil price remains the big unknown for inflation to come. It was remarked at the Q&A session that food price inflation may have peaked according to the Bank. The consolation is that higher commodity prices will very likely be accompanied by a stronger rand. If the rand price of oil remains unchanged or falls, the danger of higher interest rates will be averted for perhaps up to a further 12 months, that is until the economy gains real traction, which it will if the rand remains stable and the oil price does not detract further from household spending.

To view the graphs and tables referred to in the article, see Daily Ideas in todays Daily View:
Daily View 13 May: Think Beyond Just Inflation

Interest rates: A change of heart at the MPC?

The Monetary Policy Committee of the Reserve Bank (MPC) as expected left the Reserve Bank repo rate unchanged yesterday. While the rate was unchanged the tone of the MPC statement and of the answers to the questions posed by journalists at the media conference was very different, in our estimation, from the previous meeting. Interest rate increases were clearly very far from the minds of the MPC. The pause button on short term rates remains very much in place. The focus of the statement and the subsequent discussion was clearly on the risks to the growth and employment outlook for the SA economy rather than the risks to the inflation outlook. This was despite the inflation forecasts being revised upwards in response to higher oil and fuel prices on global markets: these are expected to approach the upper band of its 3-6 percent inflation target band.

The money market and bond market will have to revise its view of the timing of the next increase in short term rates and was in the process of doing so yesterday. Higher policy determined interest rates will be postponed until the outlook for the economy can be predicted with greater confidence and the economy is operating much closer to its potential. We regard this evidence of Reserve Bank restraint as entirely appropriate and very encouraging for the outlook for the real SA economy. Most importantly from our perspective is the explicit recognition that these price pressures are of the cost push variety rather than of demand pull variety. To quote the MPC statement: “Since the previous meeting of the Monetary Policy Committee, the risks to the outlook for domestic inflation have increased on the upside, mainly as a result of cost push pressures. The domestic growth prognosis has improved, and the recovery is expected to be sustained, although not at rates sufficient to make appreciable inroads into the unemployment situation in South Africa.

“…….At this stage there are no discernible inflationary pressures coming from the demand side of the economy….”

And in concluding remarks:

“…The MPC is of the view that the risks to the inflation outlook are on the upside. However, these risks and underlying pressures are mainly of a cost push nature…”.

To further quote the MPC:

“The trajectory of the CPI forecast of the Bank has changed somewhat since the previous meeting of the Monetary Policy Committee. Nevertheless, inflation is still expected to remain within the target range over the entire forecast period. Inflation is now expected to average 4,7 per cent in 2011 and 5,7 per cent in 2012. This represents an upward adjustment of approximately half a percentage point in both 2011 and 2012. Inflation is expected to peak at 5,8 per cent in the first quarter of 2012 before declining to 5,6 per cent in the fourth quarter. The upward adjustment is mainly due to revised assumptions regarding the international oil price over the forecast period.”

What monetary policy can’t do
Presumably the Bank has referred to cost push rather than demand pull forces on the inflation rate because monetary policy and interest rates can do little to influence cost push pressures on prices in the short run or over the relevant forecast period. This important distinction was not one easily made by the MPC before when it would refer to the danger to inflation itself of inflationary expectations themselves. Such references were happily absent this time. It has always seemed to us an argument not at all well supported by the evidence. That is inflationary expectations, as surveyed, or inflation compensation made available at the longer end of the bond market, have been largely impervious (almost always about 6% pa) to the direction of inflation itself: this has moved sharply in both directions over recent years.

The only time when inflation compensation in the bond market (being the difference between yields on conventional government bonds and inflation protected yields) moved sharply lower and then higher was at the height of the global financial crisis when risk aversion and deflation, rather than inflation itself, became the primary concern of investors.

The MPC has become anxious about the global economy and therefore the dangers of what it regards as an increasingly uncertain global economy for the SA economy where a modest recovery is now under way. The troubled sense of the MPC view of the world and of the dangers this represents for the SA economy is well captured by the following observations made in its statement: “The global economic recovery, although uneven, is expected to continue, led by a strong performance in global manufacturing. However significant downside risks remain, due to the confluence of shocks that have the potential to stall the nascent recovery. Growth in emerging markets remains robust, but Asian economies in particular may be negatively impacted by the recent developments in Japan. The global growth outlook may also be dependent on the extent to which the authorities in China manage to slow their economy down.

“….Domestic growth prospects appear to have improved moderately. Real gross domestic product grew by 2,8 per cent in 2010, and at an annualised rate of 4,4 per cent in the fourth quarter. The forecast of the Bank has increased somewhat since the previous meeting of the MPC, with GDP now expected to average 3,7 per cent and 3,9 per cent in 2011 and 2012 respectively. These growth rates, while an improvement, are still too low to have a significant impact on the unemployment rate which measured 24,0 per cent in the fourth quarter of 2010….. There are indications that although consumption expenditure growth will remain relatively robust, it is unlikely to accelerate to excessive levels in the short term…..The various house price indices all indicate that house prices are either falling or increasing at very low nominal rates. This, combined with the recent decline in equity prices, may contribute to a moderation of the impact of wealth effects on consumption.”

We welcome the emphasis the MPC is placing on the state of the economy and on the absence of demand side pressures on the economy. There is much more than inflation at risk for the SA economy and the Reserve Bank has made this very clear. This represents good news for the SA economy and we are confident that what we would regard as a change of heart of the Reserve Bank will be well received in the market place, including the currency market. Initial reactions in the bond and currency markets were positive and they are likely to remain constructive. Brian Kantor

Inflation and interest rates: The glass is half full

While headline annual consumer inflation was unchanged at 3.7% in February, the underlying trend indicates a somewhat faster rate of inflation of about 4.2%. These trends may be calculated as the monthly move in the seasonally adjusted and smoothed CPI, which is then annualised, or as the quarter to quarter annualised increases in the CPI. Both are running at a similar rate of above 4%. If the current trends are sustained the inflation rate will approach 5% over the next 12 months.


To view the graphs and tables referred to in the article, see Daily Ideas in todays Daily View:

Daily View 24 March – Inflation and Interest Rates

The forces pushing up prices are in part global in the form of rising dollar prices for food and energy. These, as the Reserve Bank pointed out in its Quarterly Bulletin, have been rising sharply as a result of increased demands and some supply side disruptions or expected disruptions in the supply of oil from the Middle East.

Breaking down the February data
The counter to such pressures has been the strength of the rand over the past 12 months. This counter pressure has been more effective in the case of food and less so for the petrol price. The food price component of the CPI is up by 3.6% compared to a year ago. Food prices actually fell by 0.1% in February 2011. The petrol price rose by 3.1% in February and higher oil prices, as well as higher excise taxes on petrol, took the year on year increase in petrol prices to 12.1%.

Food and non-alcoholic beverages account for 15.68% of the CPI basket while transport costs have a large weight of 18.8%. However Purchase of Vehicles carries by far the largest component of transport costs with a weight in the basket of 11.8% out of the 18.8% allocated to transport generally. Petrol has a weight of 3.93% and Public transport also influenced by the petrol and diesel prices has a 2.73% share of the CPI.

Owing to the downward pressure the strong rand placed on new vehicle prices, the overall transport component only increased by 2.6% over the past 12 months despite the higher petrol price. Including the prices of new vehicles rather than their implicit or explicit leasing or rental rates is surely an anomaly in the calculation of the CPI. It is the opportunity implicit or explicit leasing costs of owning a vehicle rather than the price of a vehicle that matters to households. The price of a new or used car furthermore is hardly something clearly indicated on any price list. It will be affected by financial arrangements and by warranties as well as residual and trade in values, all designed to help make a sale.

This anomaly (rentals or prices) is avoided in the case of another important category that makes up the CPI. That is the item Owners’ Equivalent Rent that makes up 12.21% of the basket with Actual rentals for housing making up a further 3.49% of the basket. Electricity prices, which rose by 18.6% over the past 12 months, have a weight of but 1.87%. Actual rents are estimated to have increased by 5.4% and owners’ equivalent rents by 3.9% over the past 12 months. Rentals were unchanged in February, presumably because they were not surveyed last month.

The future of rentals and the rate of inflation will be determined by the state of the housing market. Short term interest rates and the availability of mortgage bonds will clearly influence house prices, rents and rental returns and these will take their cue from the rand. However if house prices rise rapidly landlords may well accept a lower rental rate of return and vice versa. When house prices fall rental may prove much stickier leaving the direction of rentals somewhat independent of house price inflation.

Nevertheless home owners are likely to spend more rather than less as their balance sheets improve with higher house prices, which is unlike the case when most other prices rise. Higher (relative) prices generally restrain rather than encourage extra demands.

The right medicine
This brings attention to the most important contributor to the monthly increase of 0.7% in the CPI. Increased costs of insurance, especially medical insurance, rose by 5.2% in the month and contributed 0.4 percentage points of the increase in prices. These insurance costs are also only surveyed annually rather than monthly and revealed a year on year increase of 4.2%. Are not such increases reflective of the increasing real shortages of skilled medical personnel rather than demand side pressures on prices?

Such shortages of skills are exacerbated by the difficulties imposed by our immigration policies. They show up also in the rate of inflation of educational services provided to households. Primary and secondary education became 10.2% more expensive over the past twelve months and tertiary education was up by 7.9% over the same period.

The forces that restrain domestic inflation and the pricing power of local suppliers are the prices paid for imported goods and services and also the employment benefits received by the internationally mobile owners of scarce skills. Thus the value of the rand is the key to the underlying rate of inflation in SA.

Efforts taken to weaken the rand mean more rather than less inflation. They would also mean slower rather than faster growth, particularly in household spending, which responds favourably to lower prices and lower interest rates that follow lower prices. Growth and inflation in SA over the next twelve months will depend mostly on the global forces that determine resource and commodity prices and capital flows to emerging markets, including SA.

The most favourable outcomes for the SA economy – faster growth with low rates of inflation – will be those associated with rising commodity prices and so a strong rand. High prices for metals and minerals and inevitably also the price of oil (and also coal that we export so much of) represents good news for the SA economy. These forces proved most helpful in reviving the economy in 2010. We must hope for further fair winds to blow in from the global economy in 2011 and restraint from the SA Reserve Bank.

Money and credit: Sill growing too slowly for GDP and employment growth

The money and credit statistics released by the Reserve Bank yesterday indicate that while the money supply (broadly measured as M3) is maintaining a satisfactory rate of growth of around 7% per annum on a quarter to quarter basis, credit extended by the banks to the private sector has remained largely unchanged over the past quarter. Not coincidentally, the price of the average home in SA is also largely unchanged over the past year.

It will take an increase in mortgage credit to lift house prices, while it will take an improved housing market to encourage the banks to lend more and for property developers to wish to borrow more. The trends in money and credit supply indicate that short term interest rates are still too high rather than too low to assist the economy to realise its potential output growth. And so policy set interest rates are unlikely to increase any time soon.

The lower level of mortgage interest rates and a significantly lower debt service ratio for the average SA household  (See below) still have work to do to revive the housing market and construction activity linked to higher house prices. Perhaps the authorities, now so concerned with employment growth in SA and intending to subsidise employment with tax concessions, should be reminded that house building and renovations are highly labour intensive.

For graphs and tables, read the full Daily View here: Money and credit: Sill growing too slowly for GDP and employment growth

Rand and the economy: Why a strong rand is good for SA business

The notion that the strong rand makes life tough for SA mining enterprises is belied by the earnings now being reported by the mining companies. Anglo Plats just reported headline earnings per share of 1 935c in 2010, up from 289c in 2009, an increase of 570%. The higher US dollar price of platinum metals clearly more than made up for what a stronger rand took away.

Continue reading Rand and the economy: Why a strong rand is good for SA business

Rates decision: New governor, same stance

It seems clear that new Reserve Bank governor Gill Marcus has not yet brought anything of a different point of view to the
Monetary Policy Committee (MPC). The style was much more inclusive and open but the substance was largely the same as
before. She has deferred to the established positions of the MPC of which she is the only new member.

Therefore the sense held by the previous MPC that the economy is at a turning point and therefore needs no further
encouragement for fear of being too procyclical with interest rates (which have declined by 500bp has been maintained). Also
maintained is the concern with second round effects on inflation of electricity price increases – absent of which inflation would not
be regarded as a problem at all by the MPC.

The inflation problem is Eskom and interest rates remain where they are largely because of the Eskom effect on inflation. This
Eskom effect is creating great uncertainty and therefore is affecting inflationary expectations which are presumed to make ever
higher inflation inevitable, unless the Reserve Bank remains vigilant in setting interest rates accordingly.

Had I been at the Media Conference I would have asked this question. Does not the prospect of further electricity price increases
justify lower rather than higher interest rates given the impact of such price increases on domestic spending and therefore on
output and employment?

The answer that would have been provided would unfortunately probably have been something like as follows: no, because higher
inflation following such electricity price increases might lead to even more inflation – because of possible second round effects on
inflation.

That the MPC could still concern itself with second round inflation when the economy is as weak as it is and when the rand is as
strong as it is and when in the Reserve Bank’s view global inflation is not a threat at all to domestic inflation, speaks volumes about
the MPC’s lack of grasp of the causes and effects of supply side shocks on prices. But here nothing has yet changed with Ms
Marcus in the chair – which is the pity.

The right answer would have been yes – because Eskom’s price increase is a tax on consumers and tax increases lead to higher
prices and less spending and in the circumstances, while inflation will go up – profit margins will come down and employment
growth will remain subdued and so the economy will need some encouragement from monetary policy. Or in other words the
distinction between supply side shocks that drive inflation higher and demand led inflation should be emphasised by the
Governor. The Governor should make it clear that Monetary Policy can only be effective against demand led inflation and
monetary policy should not add to the demand reducing influence of higher levels of taxation.

Ms Marcus was also complacent about the negative growth in money supply and credit which other central banks have been very
active in trying, though not yet succeeding in combating. Again the MPC still does not wish to do anything to encourage SA banks
to ease up for the sake of the economy.

But this lack of action by the MPC was surely encouraged by a belief that the domestic economy is recovering. However such
predictions by the Reserve Bank were highly qualified as the quote from the MPC statement below indicates very clearly:

There are signs that the domestic economy will continue on its recovery path but economic growth is expected to remain below
potential for some time; and dependent to some extent on the pace of the global recovery, which still appears to be fragile and
uneven across regions. Economic growth is also expected to be constrained by subdued domestic consumption expenditure. The
domestic outlook for inflation remains favourable as a result of weak demand pressures and the main threat to the inflation outlook
emanates from possible electricity price increases.

We however see no signs of any meaningful revival in domestic spending. Reference was made to the particular unpredictability of
GDP growth this past quarter- of which preliminary estimates will be released next week. However marginally positive quarter-on-
quarter GDP growth may be recorded even as final consumption and investment demands decline. Improvements in net exports
and a reversal in inventory accumulation may yet allow GDP to grow even as final demand remains very weak. Even a modest
recovery in GDP growth would therefore not indicate the likelihood of the SA economy operating even close to its potential over
the next year – something that should concern the MPC greatly.

Should the Reserve Bank be surprised by the lack of economic recovery, it now only has its next meeting in January 2010 to
respond to it. We should not expect any emergency meeting before then and we should expect interest rates to remain on hold for
much of 2010. We can anticipate that a broader mandate for the Reserve Bank is in the offing that would allow it to concern itself
more with the growth outlook and less with the inflation outlook, especially when the inflation is supply side driven, as is clearly the
case now. We would welcome such a development as we would continue to support the independence of the Reserve Bank to act
as it judges – an independence that Governor Marcus will uphold determinedly.

The economy: Unsolicited advice for Governor Marcus

A poisoned chalice

This is not an easy time to be taking over the reins at the Reserve Bank. Spending by households and privately owned firms (which account for a very large part of the economy – up to 80% of GDP) remains in the grip of a very severe recession. More important for Gill Marcus to take into account is that there seems little sign of any imminent recovery in this spending upon which the economy depends for its growth.

For technical reasons the third quarter GDP numbers might look better because exports declined less than imports and the run down in inventories was at a slower pace than it was in the second quarter when an extraordinary reduction in inventories took as much as 10% off the GDP growth rate. But such numbers will indicate just how weak the economy is and there will be little consolation to be found in the trends in spending by the private sector.

The case for a fresh dialogue

The case for the Reserve Bank in these circumstances doing all it can to help the economy by lowering interest rates and pumping in cash to encourage the banks to lend more, might appear unassailable. However the Monetary Policy Committee found reasons at its last two meetings not to lower interest rates or to ease quantitatively.

The arguments that would have supported such inaction would presumably have included the notions that real interest rates in SA were already very low. The argument would also have been made that inflation in SA remains unsatisfactorily high and that elevated inflationary expectations could continue to have an unwelcome self fulfilling impact on inflation itself.

Ms Marcus would do well to question the validity of such arguments. It was such arguments that helped raise interest rates to recession producing levels in the first place and restrained their reversal long after it was clear that the growth in spending by households, particularly on interest sensitive durable goods was falling sharply. The damage caused to the economy is there to be seen. As we have argued before the weakness in the SA economy was of our own making. The global credit crisis made it more difficult to escape from recession.

What exactly are real interest rates?

Firstly let us raise the issue of real interest rates that may be defined as the difference between borrowing costs and inflation. By reference to CPI inflation real money market interest rates in SA may indeed appear very low. However if prices realised by producers, represented by the Producer Price Index (PPI), are taken as the point of reference real interest rates have increased to exceptionally high levels as we show below. The reason for this difference is that while consumers in SA still face inflation, producers have to deal with significant and dramatic deflation.

CPI and PPI Inflation

image002

Source: StatsSA and Investec Private Client Securities

The Consumer and Producer Price Indexes

image003

Source: StatsSA and Investec Private Client Securities

SA Real short term interest rates

image004

Source: StatsSA and Investec Private Client Securities

Real interest rates are very high – not very low

The simple idea behind the importance attached to real interest rates is that higher prices charged for goods sold offset the interest costs of borrowing. In an extreme case, if the prices firms can charge for their goods or services rise faster than the interest rates then doing no more than borrowing (cheap) money to fill up a warehouse with stuff that is bound to increase in value becomes a highly profitable business. For a household taking a loan to buy goods (a car or a house), the prices of which will rise as fast as the interest rates they are charged, may also seem like a good idea.

However as is very apparent SA households are not responding to the prospect of more inflation by borrowing more, even when banks or retailers remain willing to lend. They are borrowing less because the prices of the homes and cars and furniture they might in normal circumstances be in the market for are not expected to rise at anything like their cost of borrowing. They may even be expecting prices to fall. They will know that the rising prices they are forced to pay are for goods and services they cannot store – electricity and other municipal services that could better be described as higher taxes.

The firms that might ordinarily be encouraged to borrow funds to add to stocks and work in progress and to their complement of workers, or to add more plant and equipment, are facing and expecting deflation rather than inflation. For them the idea that their real costs of borrowing have declined is risible. Their real cost of borrowing, that is to say the real interest rates they are paying, has risen dramatically. This is why they are running down inventories, working capital and (most regrettably) workers employed.

The reality is that for producers in SA prices are falling, not rising. The further reality is that higher prices/taxes paid by their customers and themselves for electricity and other services and the higher wages they have been forced to pay their unionised workers have made it harder rather than easier for them to raise prices. The strong rand has most importantly made it more difficult for them to compete on the local or export markets. They have less, not more, pricing power because of the rising trend in CPI and wages. Their operating profits have come under such pressure and this has led them to invest less and employ fewer workers and managers.

Inflation is not a self fulfilling expectation

The notion that in these circumstances producers will not only expect more inflation but that such expectations could be self fulfilling in the absence of support from the demand side of the economy, is surely a damagingly false notion. It means damagingly high interest rates. In the absence of accommodating demands for goods and services inflationary expectations (that is to say in current circumstances, expectations of more supply side shocks for the economy in the form of higher electricity prices) will not lead to still more inflation. Supply side driven inflation expected will however lead to less output and employment. All the Reserve Bank can hope to do in such circumstances is to ease rather than add to the punishment.

The Reserve Bank needs to make the firm distinction between the inflation it does have influence over (demand led inflation) and supply side shocks that cause inflation and even expected inflation to rise – over which it has no direct influence.

Judging the right level of interest rates for SA without full regard to this distinction can prove very damaging to the economy. Interest rates influence the spending decisions of SA households and firms without necessarily having a predictable influence on the supply side of the economy and therefore on prices. The unpredictable link between interest rate changes and the exchange rate makes it even more difficult to know how interest rates will influence the inflation rate in SA.

Ms Marcus would do well to recognise these difficulties for the practice of monetary policy in SA. She should also be under no illusions that the only problem for the Reserve Bank to focus its attention upon for now is the very weak state of demand, not the rate of inflation.

The past as an irregular guide to the future

Grist for the Bears

Doug Short has attracted enormous attention to his website http://www.dshort.com/ with his “Four Bad Bear Market Analysis” (shown below and updated to Friday 28 August by its originator). The natural bears took great satisfaction from the apparently severe regularity of past bear markets, especially that of the crash of 1929. The problem for the bear lovers, as may be seen in the accompanying diagrams is that the relationship, especially with the bad bear of 1929-32, appears to have broken down in the face of the rally in stock markets that began in March 2009. The recent recovery appears by now to have extended for too long and too far to be identified as a bear market rally or a bear trap.

Cont_1.gif

Source: dshort.com

If at first you don’t succeed….

This break in the data led the inventive Doug Short (his real name assuredly) to realign the starting point for the analysis and the apparent regularities from the top of the markets before they collapsed to the following bottom, when the markets began their recovery. This new version of the analysis provided by Mr Short that demonstrates that the bottom after the crash of 1929 “failed” eleven months later, no doubt provided renewed comfort to the bears. However as may also be seen the recent rally has also by now taken the Dow beyond its gains of 1929. A new attempt to find regularities in the stock market patterns may (bulls hope) soon be called for.

Cont_2.jpe

Source: dshort.com

Bull and bear markets are only revealed with hindsight

The reality is that bear and bull markets are only identified after the event. Daily share market movements are a random walk and recent events prove no exception to this as we show below. A bear market is one when the random drift proves, well after the events, to have been generally lower and a bull market is identified after the event as a period of time when the drift was mostly higher.

In the figure below we show the pattern of daily percentage movements in the S&P 500 and the JSE All Share Indexes since the lows in the market on 9 March 2009 until the market close of Friday 28 August 2009. In the further figure we show the distribution of these daily moves about its daily average of a positive 0.02% per day with a large standard deviation of as much as 1.6% per day. The equivalent statistics for the S&P 500 are an average move of .03% per day with an even larger standard deviation of 1.7% per day. If we take the period back to the peak of the markets in May 2008 the average daily price move for the S&P 500 since then is a negative .09% per day and -0.06% per day for the JSE.

Daily percentage moves in the S&P 500 and the JSE ALSI since 9 March 2009

Cont_3.jpe

Source: I-net Bridge and Investec Private Client Securities

Histogram and Descriptive statistics for daily moves in the JSE ALSI March-August 2009

Cont_4.jpe

Source: I-net Bridge and Investec Private Client Securities

Beating the market demands careful judgment about the forces that will drive and surprise the markets

Predicting whether the continuous random drift in market indexes and share prices will be higher or lower calls for fundamental judgments about the information flows that will move the market over the following twelve or more months. The past provides us with our theories about the forces that drive markets – our theories then lead us to anticipate and predict the direction of the economic fundamentals that we believe will surprise market participants and lead the market to drift higher or lower in the course of the next twelve months or so. We have to make these predictions with humility about the difficult nature of the task of beating the well informed market.

Mining past moves in stock market indices for patterns that will repeat themselves in the future is often attempted, but in our judgment such attempts are unlikely to prove reliable in a consistent way.

How much demand led inflation is there out there?

A stubborn CPI – until you look deeper

Inflation in South Africa (6.7% in July down marginally from 6.9% in June 2009) might well be regarded as stubbornly high given the weakness of the SA economy and especially of aggregate demand. The Consumer Price Index (CPI) actually increased by as much as 1.1% in the month that if sustained would lead to an annual rate of inflation about 14%. However it hopefully will be noticed by the monetary authorities that almost all of the increase in prices in July can be attributed to increases in the charge for electricity to households and the increase in the costs of private transport.

Supply side shocks continue to drive the CPI higher

These are areas of the economy where prices are set by officials and regulators rather than market forces and are therefore not susceptible to monetary policy. These administered or regulated prices, especially electricity and water charges, are playing rapid catch up with the costs of adding to capacity to supply more such essential services. This adjustment has come after years of excess capacity and prices being regulated by reference to historic rather than replacement costs. Hopefully these supply side shocks to prices are temporary ones that end when replacement cost pricing is established. In the market place, if firms cannot realise prices that cover replacement costs – and provide a satisfactory return on capital invested – they go out of business. Publicly owned utilities with monopoly power do not go out of business – they charge higher tariffs and are infused with additional capital supplied by the tax payer.

Higher charges lead to less spending – not more inflation

Households cannot avoid paying these higher charges and this makes them less rather than more capable of spending on other goods and services. This adds to the deflationary pressure currently acting on prices that are market determined. Such forces would normally – absent of inflexible inflation targets – call for lower rather than higher interest rates to encourage more spending so badly needed to lift the economy out of recession. These deflationary forces will be revealed in gory detail when lower prices realised at the farm, factory and port gates come through in the Producer Price Index (PPI) for July, to be updated today. PPI is expected to be more than 4% lower than twelve months ago. The threat to the SA economy as most economies world wide has been and remains deflation and recession not an inflationary boom.

Looking at the CPI in detail

In the calculation of the CPI the largest weight by far (22.7%) is given to the broad category Housing and Utilities. The prices of Food and non-alcoholic beverage that account for 15.68% of the Index actually fell 0.4% in July reducing the year on year change in Food and Beverage prices (Food Inflation) to a still above average 8.3% pa. Yet it has now become clear that lower prices at producer level are feeding into lower prices for consumers. The weight attached to the electricity and other fuels account is but 1.87% and to water and other services 3.31%. However the increases in electricity and water charges in July were extraordinarily high – as much as 21.5% for electricity and 8.8% for water.

Thus the monthly increase in electricity charges contributed 0.4% of the July month increase of 1.1% and higher water charges contributed another 0.29%. The increase in Private transport costs – mostly fuel – contributed 0.20% leaving all other items with an average monthly rate of increase of 0.11% – a very low rate of inflation. Thus almost all of the increase in prices in July can be attributed to prices that are beyond the influence of consumer spending and beyond the direct influence of monetary policy and interest rates.

Whither owners equivalent rent – the key to inflation to come

The largest component in the important housing cost category is Owners Equivalent Rent with a weight of 12.21% of the CPI. This item has replaced mortgage interest in the CPI and takes its cue form average house prices of which implicit rents are some assumed fraction. Owner equivalent rent is the statistician’s equivalent of the accountant’s mark to market adjustments that has no direct impact on cash flow but can be just as confusing in its implications.

Unlike when mortgage interest rates rise or fall and add or reduce measured inflation, as used to be the case in the calculation of headline CPI, households are likely to spend more when their wealth increases with higher house prices and a higher CPI and vice versa: spend less when house prices and owners equivalent rent is falling. The task of dealing with asset price inflation – especially house price inflation – has proved beyond the capabilities of central bankers. Asset prices are now a direct influence on the SA inflation rate and will need especially careful treatment when inflation targets are being aimed at.

Owner equivalent rent did not change in July – presumably because (declining) house prices were not sampled in the month. Actual rentals (weight 3.49%) also recorded a zero change for presumably the same reason. Presumably lower house prices when surveyed will help lower owner equivalent rents and measured CPI inflation.

The problem is recession and deflation – not inflation. Will the Reserve Bank act accordingly?

The direction of prices that have been influenced by monetary policy and interest rates is decidedly downwards and is currently still adding to the recessionary pressures acting on the economy. What is required is a full recognition by the Reserve Bank of these facts of SA economic life. The Reserve Bank needs to take a leaf from the play book of most other central banks that cut interest rates sooner and much more aggressively and eased quantitatively – that is printed more money – because they recognised the immediate deflationary and recessionary dangers to the well being of their economies posed by the global credit crisis. This recognition in SA has been far too long in coming – confused as it should not have been by very different signals emanating from the direction of consumer and producer prices. Hopefully the epiphany is upon us.

Interest rate cut: A well received surprise for the market place

The 50bps reduction in the Reserve Bank Repo rate came at a distinct and welcome surprise to the market – a surprise that saw the forward short term rates and long term bond yields decline significantly. The implicit inter bank rates (JIBAR) three and six months forward rates declined by about 40bps as did the Forward rate Agreement (FRA) curve as we show below. The six month JIBAR forward rates remains above the three month rate and the FRA rates remain above the JIBAR rates, indicating that banks are paying up for longer term money. We were correct in arguing that the Bank could not ignore the further deterioration in the SA economy.

SA Banks Forward Rate Agreements

Cont_1.jpe

Source: Bloomberg and Investec Private Client Securities

JIBAR Forward Rates

Cont_2.jpe

Source: Bloomberg and Investec Private Client Securities

That the long term yield remains flat indicates that the market believes that interest rates are likely to remain at current levels for an extended period of time. The implied one year rate in ten years time is little different from the current one year rate.

The RSA Yield Curve

Cont_3.jpe

Source: Bloomberg and Investec Private Client Securities

The rand was unmoved by lower interest rates

The trade weighted rand was largely unmoved by the surprise reduction in interest rates. The decline in long term yields saw inflation compensation in the bond market, the difference between vanilla bond yields and their inflation linked equivalents, decline marginally. The yield on the inflation linked R189 also declined.

RSA Bond yields and inflation compensation

Cont_4.jpe

Source: Bloomberg and Investec Private Client Securities

Trade weighted exchange rate (higher values indicate weakness)

Cont_5.jpe

Source: Bloomberg and Investec Private Client Securities

The market reactions make the point – more than inflation targets are called for – for lower inflation

Such favourable reactions in the money and currency markets and of inflation compensation should encourage the Bank to continue to look beyond inflation as the focus of its operations. The weakness of the domestic economy remains the threat to the ability of the economy to attract foreign capital to support the rand and help hold down inflation. The economy, despite the SA recession, continues to attract foreign capital at an extraordinary rate as capital has flowed into emerging equity and bond markets, commodity markets and resource companies on recovery prospects. The SA markets have received their share of these flows – hence the strong rand that has held its own against strong other emerging and commodity market currencies.

Much more than lower interest rates are called for to help the economy

Lower interest rates can help support the longer term growth outlook and the attraction of the SA economy to foreign and local investors. But much more than lower interest rates are called for if the SA economy is to compete effectively with other emerging and commodity market destinations for capital over the next year or two. Quantitative easing, that is an increase in the rate of growth of central bank cash supplied to the system, is called for urgently to encourage the banks to lend more freely especially to households. The grave weakness in household consumption spending has to be overcome if the economy is to prosper. We have called for the Reserve Bank to supply one year money to the banks of which they continue to appear short. We would repeat this call with greater urgency.

We also welcome any temporary increase in the fiscal deficit. This is the time for the SA government to put its strong balance sheet to work to help the economy and tax revenues to recover. Hopefully stronger markets for SA exports will also assist the recovery.

The economy: Every reason to lower interest rates and to ease quantitatively

The Hard Number Index points lower

There is little comfort to be found about the current state of the SA economy in our Hard Number Index (HNI) for the SA business cycle that has been updated to July 2009. The HNI declined further from 129.48 in June to the current reading of 127.07 (2000=100). The direction of the index, its rate of change or the second derivative of the business cycle, suggest that the time when the rate of decline starts to level off is at hand though the prospects of positive growth seems some way off.

No pick up in vehicle sales or growth in the supply of cash

The HNI is an equally weighted combination of two very up to date indicators: vehicle sales; and the notes issued by the Reserve Bank, adjusted for consumer prices to provide a measure of the real money base. Both indicators are hard numbers, rather than based on sample surveys, and they are updated to the July month end. Neither series is showing improvement. The growth in the supply of cash to the system continues to slow marginally while new vehicle sales remain well below year ago levels and this deeply negative rate of growth (-40%) has not yet become obviously less negative.

The consolation to be found is in the influence of less inflation on the real supply of cash. The real money base is trending to barely positive growth.

Relief urgently called for

This data would ordinarily make it ever more obvious that the SA economy derives all the help it could get from easier monetary policy. Lower interest rates, combined with quantitative easing, both of which are active steps designed to increase the supply of cash to the banks (who are proving so reluctant to lend) are even more urgent now than they were six months ago.

The reluctance of the Reserve Bank to do what almost every other central bank has been doing to ease the pain of recession has been very difficult to appreciate. We have explained why the Bank’s concern for inflationary expectations is not sensible in these unhappy circumstances when the gap between actual and potential output of the SA economy has widened so damagingly and when prices at the factory farm and port gates as measured by the Producer Price Index (PPI), are falling so sharply. We argued that inflationary expectations were rising because it had become apparent that a change in Reserve Bank leadership was inevitable given its lack of flexibility and that more inflation tolerant policies might be adopted.

Plus ça change?

The change in leadership to come has since occurred with the prospect that low inflation over the long run will remain a primary concern of the Reserve Bank. However hopefully not regardless of the state of the economy and with attention focused only on consumer prices, which are particularly insensitive to the state of demand in the economy over which the Bank exercises its influence.

Less inflation now expected

Inflation compensation offered in the RSA bond market, being the difference in yields on offer between conventional bonds and their inflation linked equivalents have moderated recently. This is the most objective measure of inflation expected. Another measure of inflation to come is the expected direction of the rand over the long run. The difference in RSA and USA long bond yields indicates break even rand depreciation expected. That is in equilibrium the differences in nominal yields will be expected to be eliminated by a weaker rand. Thus the wider the difference in such bond yields the more rand weakness expected and so the more SA inflation on average will be expected to exceed average inflation in the US over the long run. This measure is also indicating less weakness for the rand now expected over the long run.

Ever more reason for easier monetary policy – will reason prevail?

There is therefore even more reason for lower short term interest rates in SA now than there was in June 2009. The economy has weakened further, pricing power of producers is clearly suffering further and the administered price dominated and recalibrated CPI is also rising at a slower rate than it did earlier in the year. Furthermore inflation priced into bond yields is now less than it was.

Can even the Reserve Bank with its lame duck leadership resist this evidence? We think not and expect a (surprising to the market) 50bp cut in the repo rate.

A New York state of mind: Some judgments about the economic and financial state of play

Financial markets have normalised. Much of the dislocation has been resolved – and the more obvious opportunities provided by dislocated markets have to a large degree been exercised (think of recent moves in sovereign bonds, corporate bonds, bank credit, emerging equity markets). Equity market volatility has subsided.

The US economy will come out of recession in H2 2009: positive growth will be achieved and is well under way. Preliminary Q2 estimates of GDP will be released on Friday. Even the housing market has turned with sales of new houses off their bottom. Yesterday’s Durable Goods number – excluding volatile aircraft orders – was a good number. Such a view of recession being over is not contentious but is now consensus.

The normal forces of economic growth and earnings growth surprises (up or down) therefore take over as the main drivers of equity and bond markets. Higher short and long term interest rates – while a sign of recovery under way – will not be welcome.

The key issues will be the pace of US recovery, V or U shaped – and even it is V shaped (driven by depressed output catching up with stable final demand) – the question that will be asked of the US is: can such fast growth be sustained over the next few years? That the US recovery is ahead of Europe’s should be helpful to the US dollar/euro rate of exchange.

The answer to this issue about the long term growth potential of the US economy is for observers to expect less long term growth. Given the state of fiscal policy, higher taxes and more intrusive government will be expected to restrain growth. The ability of the Fed to withdraw the punch bowl before the party gets raucous will remain a live one – inflationary expectations remain very low and explicit real interest rates remain depressed. The bond market vigilantes are sleeping soundly at home for now. Any inflation threat to bond yields and mortgage rates will be most unwelcome but always possible. Corporate bonds remain more enticing than government bonds.

Emerging market economies offer a much healthier prospect, but their equity markets have run very hard, as have their currencies. The EM index and the JSE ALSI in US dollars are both up 80% from their lows in early March and the rand is up there with the best performing EM and commodity currencies. This is a very powerful run indeed. China has led the way and possible oriental bubbles will be of concern.

The SA economy continues to languish without active enough assistance form monetary policy. But the better state of the global economy will be helpful to SA exporters. Lower inflation and the strong rand will be helpful for consumers.

Reserve Bank Governor Tito Mboweni’s decision not to lower rates in June can perhaps be regarded as a final act of defiance. Knowing (presumably) that he was to lose his job he stuck to his inflation target guns even as his ship was sinking. He had failed to seize his opportunity to save the economy with an activist programme. Even as central bankers elsewhere put on the Superman capes he remained aloof as if all that mattered was inflation. This was not only arguably an error of judgment but obviously very poor survival tactics.

The case for lower interest rates remains as strong as ever and if Gill Marcus is in the next MPC chair – one assumes she will be – she will surely wish to distance herself from her predecessor. They apparently did not get on at all well when she worked at the Bank as Deputy Governor and resigned accordingly.

There is in this author’s mind at least a 50% chance of a 50bps cut at the August MPC meeting; and if August is too soon to signal change in direction of monetary policy then there is a much greater chance of a cut, perhaps even a 100bps cut, at the following meeting. The money market is not expecting any change in rates for now – or at least wasn’t yesterday. Watch this space.

*The author wrote this piece while on a visit to the US

Expecting much from Governor Marcus

The market is waiting to see what the new Governor will deliver

The SA market in fixed interest securities has adopted a mostly wait and see attitude to the appointment of Gill Marcus as Governor of the Reserve Bank. Both long rates represented by the R157 and short term rates represented by the three month Johannesburg Inter Bank rates (Jibar) were largely unmoved in response to the surely surprising announcement. The three month forward rate agreements (FRAs) were unchanged for contracts up to six months and then recede marginally as we also show. This indicates that short rates are still not expected to be reduced for at least six months with only a slightly improved chance of lower rates beyond then (See below).

Long and short rates July 2009 (Daily Data)

Cont_12.gif

Source: I-Net Bridge and Investec Private Client Securities

Three month Forward Rate Agreements (FRAs)

Cont_13.gif

Source: Bloomberg and Investec Private Client Securities

Inflation expected remains at high levels

Expected inflation, or more correctly, compensation for bearing inflation risk in the RSA bond market, had increased sharply in Q2 2009 and has only receded slightly over the past week. This provides the most objective measure of inflation expected. Inflation compensation is measured below as the difference between the yield on the R157 and the inflation indexed R189.

The expected value of the rand has improved

The compensation for bearing the risk of rand weakness against the US dollar – based on expected differences in SA and US inflation over the long run – is recognised in the yield gap between RSA bonds and their US equivalents. This yield difference may be regarded as the market’s measure of expected exchange rate movements. This yield gap has shown little direction this year, unlike the inflation compensation series, but has receded helpfully in the past week (See below).

Inflation compensation and expected rand depreciation July 2009 (Daily data)

Cont_14.gif

Source: I-Net Bridge and Investec Private Client Securities

Mboweni took inflationary expectations very seriously

Governor Tito Mboweni paid particular attention to expected inflation when determining interest rate settings. The decision by the MPC not to reduce interest rates in June, despite the manifest weakness of domestic demand and the wide negative gap between domestic demand and potential supply, was explained as a response to more expected inflation.

The argument for combating expected, and not only actual, inflation with tighter monetary policy, is that expected inflation is self-perpetuating, that more expected inflation leads to more actual inflation. Thus monetary policy, with the long term outlook for inflation in mind, has to fight inflationary expectations as much as inflation itself.

This general argument we find hard to appreciate. For us the ability of price setters in contested markets to raise prices and to keep them up (whatever their inflationary expectations) depends on the actual state of demand. Monetary policy can influence the actual state of demand and by so doing can disabuse falsely held inflationary expectations. Furthermore profit margins may easily shrink if labour costs and employment benefits are not contained when markets conditions deteriorate. Passing on higher wages to customers in the form of higher prices will prove self defeating if demand is weak.

Worrying about inflation expectations at times like these is particularly difficult to accept

We have found such arguments about the self perpetuating nature of inflation expected particularly unhelpful now that actual demand in SA is so patently weak. The sharp deflation of prices now being realised at the SA factory doors and farm gates is very clear evidence of the weakness of aggregate demand and so the lack of pricing power enjoyed by most SA producers – despite more CPI inflation expected. The prices that have driven the CPI higher in recent months are mostly beyond the influence of monetary policy.

A much more activist approach from the Reserve Bank was called for and was not forthcoming – costing Mboweni his job

The MPC of the Reserve Bank under the direction of Mboweni has been unable to accept that monetary policy can affect demand and output and employment very severely, as it has done in SA, without necessarily having much of any immediate impact on the CPI, or indeed on inflationary expectations. The failure of the Bank under Mboweni to adapt monetary policy aggressively and actively, in unusually difficult times and conditions, with appropriate and convincing analysis and explanations, surely made Mboweni’s reappointment politically impossible. The focus of inflation and inflation expectations was not good enough for the times.

The market knew that Mboweni’s tenure was limited – hence more inflation expected

The notion that inflation would rise permanently in SA after Mboweni was inevitably to be replaced by somebody much less concerned about inflation and after the independence of the Reserve Bank had been compromised, understandably gained credence. Hence the increased inflationary expectations the Reserve Bank were fighting so unwisely were unfortunately and unintentionally much of the Reserve Bank’s own making.

Marcus must disabuse markets of the notion of permanently high inflation – by demonstrating a sensible and sensitive regard for the state of the economy

The appointment of Gill Marcus holds every promise of disabusing the markets of the notion that inflation in SA is permanently on the rise. But it will take sensible and sensitive monetary policy to do so. Monetary policy must take and must be seen to take full account of the state of the economy as well as of the causes and consequences of inflation and inflationary expectations for the economy. The current emphasis on fighting inflation has to be moderated with out compromising the importance the Reserve Bank attaches and is believed to attach to realising low inflation as the means to the end of a more efficient economy.

The independence of any central bank is always conditional on its ability to convince the public and the politicians who represent public opinion, that it is fully capable of helping the economy realise its potential- with the aid of low inflation. Ms Marcus will undoubtedly be very well aware of the importance for sustaining the independence of the Bank from direct political interference, of not only doing well by the economy, but of being seen and understood to be doing what is sensible and right for the economy.