Sending in the helicopters – monetary and fiscal policy in the developed world and SA

The term “helicopter money” has gained currency among economists and policymakers in recent times. We discuss the practical implications of this policy tool and contrast the challenges faced by developed markets with those of SA

After several years of quantitative easing (QE) – the process whereby the central bank buys up assets like government bonds in order to inject cash into the monetary system – the developed world has found that, while outright disaster may have been averted, it has not delivered the robust growth that was hoped for.

Economists and policymakers are now considering other stimulatory tools, including fiscal measures and “helicopter money” to lift developed market economies out of the apparent quagmire of very low growth.

The notion (metaphor) of helicopter money (also known as “QE for the people”) was first invoked by the foremost monetarist Milton Friedman and revived by Ben Bernanke, later chairman of the US Federal Reserve (Fed), to indicate how central banks might overcome a theoretical possibility that has become a very real problem for central bankers today.

The metaphor was derived from a parable in Friedman’s famous 1969 paper “The Optimum Quantity of Money”:

Let us suppose now that one day a helicopter flies over this community and drops an additional $1,000 in bills from the sky, which is, of course, hastily collected by members of the community. Let us suppose further that everyone is convinced that this is a unique event which will never be repeated.

The idea was picked up in subsequent years by others, including Bernanke, who noted in 2002 (while still a Fed governor) while speaking about deflation in Japan, how John Maynard Keynes “once semi-seriously proposed, as an anti-deflationary measure, that the government fill bottles with currency and bury them in mine shafts to be dug up by the public”. Bernanke added that “a money-financed tax cut is essentially equivalent to Milton Friedman’s famous ‘helicopter drop’ of money.”

The concept has gained further currency in recent years in the light of extremely low inflation in many developed economies. In this article, we look at some of the implications and practicalities of such measures and then contrast this with the policy approach that has been used in SA. First however, some context on the policy of QE that has become the mainstay for central banks in the developed world over the last eight years or so.

A question of QE

Central banks of the US, Europe and Japan, have created vast quantities of extra money in recent years through QE, quantities that would have been unimaginable before the Global Financial Crisis of 2008. Unfortunately, these have been bottled up in the banks who have held on to the extra cash received rather than used it to make loans that would have helped their economies along.

The cash was received by the banks or their customers from the central banks in exchange for government bonds and other securities bought from them in the credit markets and directly from the banks themselves. The cash shows up as extra deposits held by private deposit taking banks with their central banks – the bankers to the banks. This process of QE has led to the creation of trillions of dollars, euros or other currencies of extra assets held by central banks – matched by an equal growth in their liabilities, mostly to the banking system in the form of these extra deposits (see below).

Source: Federal Reserve Bank – Recent Balance Sheet Trends

Figure 2: Federal Reserve System of the US: Total assets and composition of assets

Source: Federal Reserve Bank – Recent Balance Sheet Trends

But why did these central banks create the extra cash in such extraordinary magnitude? In the US it was to rescue the banking and insurance systems from collapse in the face of their losses incurred in the debt markets following the failure of a leading bank, Lehman Brothers, that might have brought down the financial system with it. In Europe it was to prevent a meltdown in the market for most European government debt that could have brought down all lenders to government – not only banks but pension funds and insurance companies and their dependents. In Switzerland the cash came from purchases by the central bank of dollars and euros that flooded into the Swiss banking system and would otherwise have driven the Swiss franc even stronger than it has become. In Japan the extra cash was designed to offset the recessionary and deflationary forces long plaguing the economy.

The original purpose of QE in the US and Europe was to prevent a financial collapse. The second related reason was to fight recession and deflation. Extra money and the lower interest rates accompanying it are meant to encourage extra spending and lending. Extra money and lower interest rates usually do this to an economy – stimulate demand. Usually with extra demand comes higher prices and inflation.

The banks receive the extra cash directly from the central bank in exchange for the securities previously held on their own balance sheets or they may receive the extra central bank cash, with the deposits made by their clients when banking the proceeds of their own asset sales. Their clients deposit the cheques or, more likely, EFTs issued by the central bank in their private banking accounts and the banks then receive an equivalent credit on their own deposit accounts with the central bank as the cheques on the central bank are cleared or the EFTs are given electronic effect. And so in this way, through asset purchases by the central bank acting on its own initiative, extra central bank money enters the financial system, a permanent increase that can only be reversed when the central bank sells down the securities it has bought.

The banks have an option to hold the extra cash rather than lend it out to firms or households, who would ordinarily spend the cash so made available. And banks in the US, Japan, the Eurozone, UK and Switzerland have done just this in an extreme way. They are holding the extra cash supplied to them by their central banks as additional cash reserves, way in excess of the requirement to hold them.

The US money base shown below is the sum of currency and bank deposits (adjusted for reserve requirements) held with the central bank. Note how the US money base has grown in line with excess reserves held by the Fed and the extraordinary growth in the deposits held by Swiss banks with the Swiss National Bank.

Figure 4: Adjusted monetary base of the US

Figure 5: Excess reserves of US depository institutions

Figure 6: Swiss monetary base

Bringing in the helicopters

It’s here where the call comes in for metaphorical helicopters to bypass the banking system and jettison bundles of cash that people would pick up gratefully and spend on goods and services, so reviving a stagnant economy (stagnant for want of enough demand, not for want of potential output and employment that is the usual economic problem).

But will the helicopters come in the form imagined by Friedman, Bernanke and others? In reality they are likely to take a different form. They will have to be ordered by governments and budgeted for in Congresses or Parliaments. Central banks can buy assets in the financial markets and directly from banks. They cannot order up government spending that they can help fund. That is the job of governments, who decide how much to spend and how to fund it. Governments can fund spending by taxing their citizenry, which means they (the citizens) will have less to spend. This is never very popular with voters. They can also fund government spending by genuine borrowing in the market place – competing with other potential borrowers – crowding them out by offering market-related interest rates and other terms to lenders. Or they can fund their expenditure by calling on the central bank for loans that, as a government agency, they cannot easily refuse to do.

In taking up the securities offered to them by the government, the central bank credits the deposit accounts of the government and its agencies with the central bank to the same (nominal) value as the debt offered in exchange. Both the assets and deposit liabilities of the central bank then increase by the same sum, as the extra debt is bought by the central banks and the government deposit credited. As the government agencies write cheques on their deposit account – or do the EFTs on them – the government deposit runs down and the deposits of the private banks with the central bank run up. In this way, the supply of cash held by the private sector increases, just as it does in the case of QE.

And the private banks and their customers will have the same choice about what to do with the extra cash held on their own balance sheets. Spend more, lend more or pay back debts or hold the extra cash, as they have largely been doing.

But there is an important difference when the money is created to fund extra government spending. Spending by government on goods, services or labour (or perhaps welfare grants) will have increased, so directly adding to aggregate spending. By spending more, the revenues of business suppliers and the incomes of households will have risen with their extra money balances received for their services or benefits. This makes it more likely that they will spend at least some of their extra income, generating what is known in economics as a multiplier effect. This is why spending by government can be highly inflationary, as it was in the Weimar Republic of Germany after World War 1 or as it was in Zimbabwe not so long ago or as it is now driving prices higher in Venezuela.

But the current danger in the West is deflation, the result of too little, rather than too much spending. Inflation seems very far away, as revealed by the very low or even negative interest rates offered by a number of governments (in the form of negative yields on government debt) to willing lenders for extended periods of time. For some governments, issuing debt – at negative interest rates that produces an income for the government – is cheaper than issuing cash, that is the non-interest bearing debt of the government and usually the cheapest method for funding its expenditure. How can they resist the temptation to generate government income by issuing more debt for an extended period of time? Not easily, we would suggest.

The continued weakness of developed economies suffering from a lack of demand, despite low interest rates, calls for money and debt – or money creation by governments. The call for less austerity or more government spending relative to taxes collected, is being heard in Japan. It is a voice being sounded loud and clear in post-Brexit Britain. The Italians are very anxious to use government money to revive their own failed banking system. The Germans, with their own particular Weimar inflation demons, will however resist the idea of central banks directly funding governments, but for how long? Hillary Clinton promises spending on infrastructure. Donald Trump worries little about debt of all kinds – including his own (for now, as far as we can tell).

How long can weak economies co-exist with very low interest rates and abundant supplies of cash? It will not take helicopters but unhappy voters to stimulate more government spending, funded with cheap debt or cash. And the voters appear particularly restless on both sides of the Atlantic and, for that matter, the Mediterranean. The next few years promise to be intriguing ones for the governments and electorates of these countries.

Meanwhile in SA – a different world

At this point it is worthwhile to compare and contrast policy actions in the developed world with those in SA. The Reserve Bank (the Bank) has not practised QE. By contrast, SA banks, rather than being inundated with cash and excess reserves, have been kept consistently short of cash in support of the interest rate settings of the Bank. SA banks borrow cash from the Bank rather than hold excess cash reserves with it.

SA banks do not therefore hold reserves in the form of deposits at the central bank in excess of the reserves they are required to hold. As may be seen in the figures below, by contrast with their developed world counterparts, the SA banks are kept short of cash through liquidity absorbing operations by the Bank and, more importantly, by the SA National Treasury.

Also to be noted is the liquidity provided consistently to the banking system by the Bank in the form of repurchases of assets from them as well as loans against reserve deposits. Rather than holding excess reserves over required cash reserves, the SA banks consistently borrow cash from the Bank to satisfy their regulated liquidity requirements.

It is these loans to the banking system that give the Bank its full authority over short-term interest rates. The repo rate, at which it makes cash available to the banks, is the lowest rate in the money market from which all other short-term interest rates take their cue. Keeping the banks short of cash ensures that changes in the policy-determined repo rate is made effective in the money market – that is, all other rates will automatically follow the repo rate because the banks are kept short of cash and borrow reserves rather than hold excess cash reserves.

In the US, the Fed pays interest on the deposit reserves banks hold with the Fed. The European Central Bank (ECB), for its part, applies a negative rate to the reserves banks hold with it. In other words, Eurozone banks have to pay rather than receive interest on the balances they keep with the ECB as an inducement to them to lend rather than hoard the cash they receive via QE.

The cash reserves the SA banks acquire originate mostly through the balance of payments flows. Notice in the figure below that the assets of the Bank are almost entirely foreign assets. Direct holdings of government securities are minimal, as reflected on the Bank balance sheet. When the balance of payments (BOP) flows are positive, the Bank can add to its foreign assets and when they are negative, run them down. The Bank buys foreign exchange in the currency market from the private banks (and credits their deposit accounts with the Bank accordingly) or sells foreign exchange to them and then calls on their deposit accounts with the Bank for payment.

Thus, when the BOP flows are favourable, the Bank may be adding to its foreign assets and so to the foreign exchange reserves of SA via generally anonymous operations in the foreign exchange market. In so doing, it is acting as a residual buyer or seller of foreign exchange and, as such, will be preventing exchange rate changes from balancing the supply and demand. With a fully flexible exchange rate, no changes in foreign exchange reserves would be observed, only equilibrating movements in exchange rates. The exchange rate will strengthen or weaken to equalise supply and demand for US dollars or other currencies on any one trading day without causing any change in the supply of cash, that is in the sum of bank deposits held with the Bank.

The foreign assets on the Bank balance sheet have however increased consistently over the years as we show in the figure below. Hence influence of the BOP on the money base (on the cash reserves of the banks) has been a strongly positive one.

Without intervention in the money market, these purchases of foreign exchange by the Bank would automatically lead to an equal increase in the cash reserves of the banking system. Their deposits at the Bank would automatically reflect larger deposit balances as foreign exchange is acquired from them and their clients. This source of cash however has been offset by SA National Treasury operations in the money and securities markets.

To sterilise the potential increase in the money base of the system (defined as notes plus bank deposits at the central banks less required reserves) the Treasury issues more debt to the capital market. The debt is sold to the banks and their customers – they draw on their deposits to pay for the extra issues of debt – and the Treasury keeps the extra proceeds on its own government deposit account with the Bank. Provided these extra government deposits are held and not spent by the Treasury – as is the policy intention – the BOP effects on the money base (on bank deposits or reserves) will have been neutralised by increases in government deposits. (The money base only includes bank deposits with the Reserve Bank. Government deposits are not part of the money base.)

It is to be noted in the figure representing Reserve Bank Liabilities, how the Government Deposits with the Reserve Bank have grown as the Foreign Assets of the Bank have increased – extra liabilities for the Reserve Bank offsetting extra foreign assets held by the Bank. It is of interest to note that about half of the Treasury deposits at the Reserve Bank are denominated in foreign currencies.

Figure 7: SA Reserve Bank balance sheet: Assets

Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment

Figure 8: SA Reserve Bank: Selected liabilities

Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment

The net effect of recent activity in the money market has meant much slower growth in the supply of cash and deposits with the banking system. Despite the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves and because of the sterilisation operations undertaken by the Treasury, the money base in SA has grown relatively slowly, as have the broader measures of the money supply, M2 or M3, that incorporate almost all of the deposit liabilities of the banks to their creditors. This has been matched by equally slow growth in the supply of and demand for bank credit that makes up much of the asset side of bank balance sheets. This slow growth has been entirely consistent with weak growth in aggregate spending and GDP. Compare and contrast this with how rapidly money and credit grew in the boom years of 2004-2008 (see below).

Figure 9: Growth in SA money base (adjusted for reserve requirements) and broadly defined money supply (M3)

Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment

Figure 10: Growth in S money supply (M3) and bank credit and direction of the business cycle

Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment

The shortcomings of SA monetary policy

One test of monetary policy is its ability to moderate the amplitude of the business cycle. The strength of the boom between 2004 and 2008 and the subsequent collapse – and the persistently slow growth in money credit and spending after 2011 – indicates that monetary policy in SA has not been notably counter-cyclical. Nor can it claim much success in limiting inflation even as growth in aggregate spending (Gross Domestic Expenditure – GDE) and output (Gross Domestic Product – GDP) has remained very depressed.

Economic activity picked up when inflation subsided between 2003 and 2005, because the exchange value of the rand recovered strongly and because interest rates declined with less inflation. The SA economy enjoyed boom time conditions between 2004 and 2007. The interest rate cycle turned higher in 2006, well before the Global Financial Crisis broke in September 2008 and yet was accompanied by rand weakness. Inflation accelerated in 2006-7 as the exchange rate weakened and inflation rates remained high as exchange rate weakness persisted until early 2009. Lower interest rates followed a rand recovery in 2009 and lower inflation rates that continued until mid-2010. Interest rates were stable to marginally lower until the end of 2013, but reversed course in early 2014 after inflation picked up and came to threaten the upper band of the inflation targets set for the Reserve Bank. This higher inflation followed the high degree of rand weakness after 2011 that was linked (mostly) to global risk aversion and lesser flows to emerging market bonds and equities. This rand weakness persisted until May 2016 as the economy slowed down markedly under the influence of higher prices and higher interest rates. These higher interest rates further weakened demand that was already under pressure from higher prices, without appearing to do anything to slow down inflation. Inflation continued to tack its cue from a persistently weaker rand, while a drought and higher prices for staple foods added materially to measured inflation in 2015-2016.

These dilemmas for a monetary policy that attempts to meet inflation targets, without regard to the causes of inflation – the result of fewer goods and services supplied rather than more demanded – has meant having to sacrifice growth without reducing inflation. Such unfortunate trade-offs for monetary policy – achieving slower growth yet accompanied by more inflation – will persist if exchange rate changes remain largely driven by global forces or other supply side shocks. These include drought or higher expenditure taxes, to which the Bank has responded with higher interest rates regardless of the causes of inflation. For the history of inflation, interest and exchange rates since 2000, see the figure below that identifies the phases of higher and lower interest rates.

Figure 11: Interest rates, inflation rates and the trade weighted rand (2000-2016)

Source: SA Reserve Bank and Investec Wealth & Investment

The recovery in the rand over the last few months offers the hope of a cyclical recovery, similar to events after 2003 – though should it materialise it is unlikely to be of the same strong amplitude. The stronger rand brings less inflation in its wake, as would any normal harvest. Less inflation means less inflation expected and a much improved chance of interest rates falling rather than rising, as they have been doing since January 2014.

Some hope of an economic revival is in the spring air

The Reserve Bank, not before time, has changed its tone. It has suggested that the interest rate cycle may have peaked. From the pause in the trend to higher rates we now have talk of a longer pause in interest rate settings. If the exchange rate holds up better than R14 to the US dollar by the next time the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) meets in November, interest rates may well be on their way down. The Bank’s inflation forecast (if not the year on year change in the CPI, headline inflation itself) will have had time to adjust lower and food price inflation will be in retreat from its extraordinarily elevated 12% plus base. How rapidly this occurs will depend on the rain. Prayers for rain are in order.

If all goes better on the inflation front, the Reserve Bank will be able to focus on something very important to the SA economy over which it does have considerable influence and that is domestic spending and lending. Its interest rate settings do predictably affect the willingness of households and firms to spend more; and the SA economy urgently needs the stimulus of more demand and lower interest rates.

These interest rates however have no predictable influence on the exchange rate, rainfall or on excise and other taxes, including fuel and sugar taxes. Nor do they affect the price of electricity except, perversely, should Eskom persuade Nersa, the regulator, that its higher borrowing and other costs are a good (actually bad) excuse for a higher tariff. Nor, as I would argue, though the MPC would disagree, do higher interest rates influence inflationary expectations for the better and/or wage demands for the better.

Inflation expected (which has remained remarkably stable and consistent around the 6% – the upper band of the inflation target level will follow inflation – not the other way round. Inflation leads and inflation expected follows, as will be further demonstrated should inflation come down because the rand has strengthened and long term interest rates decline relative to US interest rates, meaning less rand weakness expected and hence less inflation expected. This narrowing of the spread between RSA and US benchmark interest rates has been under over the past few days. It is a very helpful development.

With some help from global capital flows, the weather and the politicians (and also the rating agencies) we will see the rand hold up inflation and the inflation forecasts continue to recede. The question then will be how low can interest rates in SA go. I would suggest as low as it takes to get the growth in spending running at a sustainable 3- 4% per annum. The sustainability of such growth will depend upon support from capital inflows and so a stable rand itself. Faster growth itself will be very encouraging not only to capital expenditure by firms and the government – but to global suppliers of capital. Can we dare hope for a virtuous cycle of faster growth with less inflation? A reprise perhaps of 2003-2008, accompanied by much better control of money supply and bank credit?

Features of the SA monetary system

We continue from our discussion of “helicopter money” (see Point of View: Helicopters in a different form, 1 August 2016) with a description and analysis of the SA monetary system. The Reserve Bank of SA has not practiced quantitative easing. By contrast, SA banks rather than being inundated with cash and excess reserves, have been kept consistently short of cash in support of the interest rate settings of the Reserve Bank. SA banks borrow cash from their central banks rather than hold excess cash reserves with it.

The SA Reserve Bank has not practised quantitative easing (QE). SA banks have not been inundated with cash derived from asset purchases in the securities market as had been the case in the developed world. Rather, SA monetary policy in recent years has practised a pro-cyclical policy with interest rates rising and subdued base money supply growth.

SA banks do not therefore hold reserves in the form of deposits at the central bank in excess of the reserves they were required to hold. As may be seen in the figures below, by contrast with their developed world counterparts, the SA banks are kept short of cash through liquidity absorbing operations by the Reserve Bank and, more importantly, by the SA Treasury.

Also to be noted is the liquidity provided consistently to the banking system by the Reserve Bank in the form of repurchases of assets from them as well as loans against reserve deposits. Rather than holding excess reserves over required cash reserves, the SA banks consistently borrow cash from the Reserve Bank to satisfy their regulated liquidity requirements.

It is these loans to the banking system that give the Reserve Bank full authority over short-term interest rates. The repo rate at which it makes cash available to the banks is the lowest rate in the money market from which all other short term interest rates take their cue. Keeping the banks short of cash ensures that changes in the policy-determined repo rate is made effective in the money market – that is, all other rates will automatically follow the repo rate because the banks are kept short of cash and borrow reserves rather than hold excess cash reserves.

In the US, the Fed pays interest on the deposit reserves banks hold with the Fed. The ECB, by contrast, applies a negative rate to the reserves banks hold with it. In other words, European banks have to pay rather than receive interest on the balances they keep with the ECB.

The cash reserves the banks acquire originate mostly through the balance of payments flows. Notice that the assets of the Reserve Bank are almost entirely foreign assets. Direct holdings of government securities are minimal, as reflected on the Reserve Bank balance sheet. When the balance of payments (BOP) flows are positive, the Reserve Bank adds to its foreign assets and when negative runs them down. The Reserve Bank buys foreign exchange in the currency market from the banks (and credits their deposit accounts with the Reserve Bank accordingly) or sells foreign exchange to them and then draws on their deposit accounts with the Reserve Bank as payment.

And so when the BOP flows are favourable, the Reserve Bank will be adding to its foreign assets and so to the foreign exchange reserves of SA via generally anonymous operations in the foreign exchange market. In so doing it is acting as a residual buyer or seller of foreign exchange and as such will be preventing exchange rate changes from balancing the supply and demand for foreign exchange. In a fully flexible exchange rate no changes in foreign exchange reserves would be observed, only equilibrating movements in exchange rates. The exchange rate will strengthen or weaken to equalise supply and demand for US dollars or other currencies on any one trading day. The Foreign Assets on the Reserve Bank balance sheet have increased consistently over the years. Hence the balance of payments influence on the money base- on the cash reserves of the banks- has been a strongly positive one.

Without intervention in the money market, these purchases of foreign exchange by the Reserve Bank would automatically lead to an equal increase in the cash reserves of the banking system. Their deposits at the Reserve Bank would automatically reflect larger deposit balances as foreign exchange is acquired from them and their clients. This source of cash however has been offset by SA Treasury operations in the money and securities markets.

To sterilise the potential increase in the money base of the system (defined as notes plus Bank Deposits at the central banks less required reserves) the Treasury issues more debt to the capital market. The debt is sold to the banks and their customers – they draw on their deposits to pay for the extra issues of debt – and the Treasury keeps the extra proceeds on its own government deposit account with the Reserve Bank. Provided these extra government deposits are held and not spent by the Treasury – as is the policy intention – the BOP effects on the money base (on bank deposits or reserves) will have been neutralised by increases in government deposits. (The money base only includes bank deposits with the Reserve Bank. Government deposits are not part of the money base.)
It is to be noted in the figure representing Reserve Bank Liabilities, how the Government Deposits with the Reserve Bank have grown as the Foreign Assets of the Reserve Bank have increased – extra liabilities for the Reserve Bank offsetting extra foreign assets held by the Reserve Bank. It is of interest to note that about half of the Treasury deposits at the Reserve Bank are denominated in foreign currencies.

 

The net effects of recent activity in the money market has meant much slower growth in the money base and the money and bank credit supplies over recent years. This slow growth has been entirely consistent with weak growth in aggregate spending and GDP. Note below how rapidly money and credit grew in the boom years of 2004-2008.

 

One test of monetary policy is its ability to moderate the amplitude of the business cycle. The strength of the boom between 2005 and 2008 and the subsequent collapse – and the persistently slow growth in money credit and spending after 2011 – indicates that monetary policy in SA has not been notably counter-cyclical. Nor can it claim much success in limiting inflation.

The problem for monetary policy in SA is the independent (of monetary policy settings) role played by the exchange rate in determining prices. Inflation has followed the exchange rate rather than money supply and interest rates. And the exchange rate movements have been dominated by global events- flows into and out of emerging market currencies (of which the rand is one) in response to global risk.

Economic activity picked up when inflation subsided between 2003- 2005, because the exchange value of the rand recovered strongly and because interest rates declined with less inflation. Inflation accelerated in 2008-9 as the exchange rate weakened and remained high with persistent exchange rate weakness. Interest rates were moved higher after 2014 as inflation picked up and the economy slowed down, further weakening demand without appearing to do anything to slow down inflation. These dilemmas for monetary policy will persist if exchange changes remain largely driven by global forces rather than SA interest rates.

An influence on this money multiplier in SA has been changes in the banks’ demands to hold notes in their tills and ATMs. The ratio of notes held by the banks to all notes in circulation fell away sharply after 2000, thus adding to the money multiplier. This ratio has increased more recently, so reducing the money multiplier. The Reserve Bank influenced this demand for notes by the banks by deciding in the early 2000s not to include notes held by the banks qualifying as required cash reserves.

Helicopters in a different form

It is not helicopters but old fashioned government spending – funded by debt or cash – that will be called into action to get developed market economies going again.

The notion (metaphor) of helicopter money was first invoked by the foremost monetarist Milton Friedman and revived by Ben Bernanke, later Governor of the US Fed, to indicate how central banks might overcome a theoretical possibility that has in reality become a very real problem for central bankers today. The problem for the central banks of the US, Europe and especially Japan is that the vast quantities of extra money they have created in recent years, quantities of money that would have been unimaginable before the Global Financial Crisis of 2008, have been bottled up in the banks who have held on to the extra cash received rather than used it to make loans that would have helped their economies along.

The cash was received by the banks or their customers from the central banks in exchange for the government and other securities bought from them in the credit markets and directly from the banks themselves. The cash shows up as extra deposits held by the private deposit taking banks with their central banks – the bankers to the banks. It has been a process of money creation described as quantitative easing (QE) that has led to trillions of dollars, euros or other currencies of extra assets held by central banks – matched by an equal growth in their liabilities, mostly to the banking system in the form of extra deposits held with the central bank (see below).

But why did these central banks create the extra cash in such extraordinary magnitude? In the first place in the US it was to rescue the banking and insurance systems from collapse in the face of their losses incurred in the debt markets that led to the failure of a leading bank Lehman that might have brought down the financial system with it. In Europe it was to prevent a meltdown in the market for most European government debt that could have brought down all lenders to government – not only banks but pension funds and insurance companies and their dependents. In Switzerland the cash came from purchases by the central bank of dollars and euros that flooded into the Swiss banking system and would otherwise have driven the Swiss Franc even stronger than it has become. In Japan the extra cash was always designed to offset the recessionary and deflationary forces long plaguing the economy.The original purpose of QE in the US and Europe was to prevent a financial collapse. The second related reason was to fight recession and deflation. Extra money and the lower interest rates accompanying it are meant to encourage extra spending and extra lending to the same purpose. Extra money and lower interest rates usually do this to an economy – stimulate demand. Usually with extra demand comes higher prices and inflation.

The banks receive the extra cash directly from the central bank in exchange for the securities previously held on their own balance sheets or who may receive the extra central bank cash firstly with the deposits made by their clients when banking the proceeds of their own asset sales. Their clients deposit the cheques or, more likely, EFTs issued by the central bank in their private banking accounts and the banks then receive an equivalent credit on their own deposit accounts with the central bank as the cheques on the central bank are cleared or the EFTs’ given electronic effect. And so in this way, through asset purchases by the central bank acting on its own initiative, extra central bank money enters the financial system, a permanent increase that can only be reversed when the central bank sells down the securities it has bought.

The banks have an option to hold the extra cash rather than lend it out to firms or households, who would ordinarily spend the cash so made available. And banks in the US, Japan, England and Europe and Switzerland have done just this in an extreme way. They are holding the extra cash supplied to them by their central banks as additional cash reserves way in excess of the requirement to hold reserves.

The US Money Base shown below is the sum of currency and bank deposits (adjusted for reserve requirements) held with the central bank (see below the US Money Base that has grown in line with excess reserves held by the Fed and the extraordinary growth in the deposits held by Swiss banks with the Swiss National Bank).

 

And so the call for the imaginary helicopters to bypass the banking system and jettison bundles of cash that people would pick up gratefully and spend on goods and services so reviving a stagnant economy (stagnant for want of enough demand, not for want of potential output and employment that is the usual economic problem).

The helicopters however will have to take a different form. They will have to be ordered by governments and budgeted for in Congresses or Parliaments. Central banks can buy assets in the financial markets and directly from banks. They cannot order up government spending that they can help fund. That is the job of governments who decide how much to spend and how to fund their spending. Governments can fund spending by taxing their citizenry, which means they will have less to spend. This is never very popular with voters. They can fund government spending by genuine borrowing in the market place – competing with other potential borrowers – crowding them out by offering market-related interest rates and other terms to lenders. Or they can fund their expenditure by calling on the central bank for loans that, as a government agency, they cannot easily refuse to do.

In taking up the securities offered to them by the government the central bank credits the deposit accounts of the governments to the same (nominal) value as the debt offered in exchange. Both the assets and deposit liabilities of the central bank then increase by the same sum as the extra debt is bought by the central banks and the government deposit credited. As the government agencies write cheques on their deposit account – or do the EFTs on them – the government deposit runs down and the deposits of the private banks with the central bank run up. In this way, the supply of cash held by the private sector increases, just as it does in the case of QE.

And the private banks and their customers will have the same choice about what to do with the extra cash held on their own balance sheets. Spend more, lend more or pay back debts or hold the extra cash, as they have largely been doing.

But there is an important difference when the money is created to fund extra government spending. Spending by government on goods services or labour or perhaps welfare grants will have increased, so directly adding to aggregate spending. By spending more, the revenues of business suppliers and the incomes of households will have risen with their extra money balances received for their services or benefits. This is why spending by government – funded with extra money is usually highly inflationary – can be highly inflationary as it was in the Weimar Republic of Germany after World War 1 or as it was in Zimbabwe not so long ago or as it is now driving prices higher in Venezuela.

But the current danger in the West is deflation, the result of too little rather than too much spending. Inflation seems very far away, as revealed by the very low or even negative interest rates offered by a number of governments to willing lenders for extended periods of time. For some government issuing debt – at negative interest rates that produces an income for the government – is cheaper than issuing cash that gives only a zero rate of interest.

The continued weakness of developed economies suffering from a lack of demand, despite low interest rates, calls for money and debt and or money creation by governments. The call for less austerity or more government spending relative to taxes collected is being heard in Japan. It is a voice being sounded loud and clear in post Brexit Britain. The Italians are very anxious to use government money to revive their own failed banking system. The Germans with their own particular inflation demons will however resist the idea of central banks directly funding governments, but for how long? Hillary Clinton promises spending on infrastructure. Donald Trump worries about government debt – for now as far as we can tell.

How long can weak economies and very low interest rates and abundant supplies of cash co-exist? It will not take helicopters but unhappy voters to stimulate more government spending, funded with cheap debt or cash. And the voters appear particularly restless on both sides of the Atlantic and, for that matter, the Mediterranean. 1 August 2016

A fuller account of the above discussion can be found here: Money supply and economic activity in South Africa – The relationship updated to 2011

The end of higher interest rates is in sight – a different monetary policy narrative is still called for

The end of the current cycle of rising short term interest rates in SA that began in January 2014 is thankfully in sight.

Given the continued weakness of demand for goods and services, it will take the assumption of a more or less stable rand about current rates of exchange rates to bring inflation and forecasts of inflation in 2017 well below the upper 6% band of the inflation targets. The Reserve Bank model of inflation has reduced its estimate of headline inflation in December 2016 to 7.1%, from its May forecast of 7.3%.

The Bank, which was predicting a gradual decline in headline inflation in 2017, has maintained its central estimate of inflation in December 2017 at 5.5%. It has revised lower its already weak GDP growth forecasts. It is forecasting no growth in 2016 (previously 0.6% p.a) and an anemic 1.1% p.a. GDP growth in 2017 compared to 1.3% p.a estimated previously. Our own exercise in simulating the Reserve Bank forecasting model, using current exchange rates, has generated the following forecasts for headline inflation (see below). The Governor indicated that the Bank’s own forecasts were made with unchanged assumptions about the exchange rate, hence the slightly higher estimates of inflation.

 

combination of very slow growth with less inflation vitiates any possible argument for higher interest rates for now and hopefully for an extended period of time to come.

Should inflation sustain a downward trend and growth in SA remain well below potential growth, the case for cutting rates to stimulate growth will become irresistible in due course. Food prices off their high levels brought by the drought have already stopped rising (according to the June CPI) and so will help materially to reduce the rate at which prices in general rise next year. The chances have improved for a very helpful inflation and interest rate surprise in the downward direction.

These developments in the currency and capital markets beg a question difficult to answer, given the impossibility of re-winding the economic clock. Did the interest rate increases imposed on a fragile economy do anything at all to hold back inflation?

Given the global forces that have driven the exchange value of the rand and all emerging market currencies weaker, it is not at all obvious that higher interest rates have made the rand more attractive to hold or acquire. Nor will interest increases have done anything at all to have offset the impact of the Zuma intervention in fiscal affairs that made the rand such an underperforming emerging currency and bond market until recently. Indeed, by further slowing down growth, higher interest rates may have discouraged investment in SA and weakened rather than strengthened the rand, while clearly discouraging the credit rating agencies and investors in the RSA bond market, leading to higher long term interest rates.

Recent trends in the rand and other emerging market (EM) currencies are shown below. We show how the rand has made some gains against other EM currencies recently. We also show that after significant weakness in 2015, the rand in 2016 has now gained against the Aussie dollar and gained even further against sterling. The impact of the Zuma intervention in December 2015 and Brexit on the rand is indicated.

 

What must be conceded is the role of Reserve Bank rhetoric about interest rates – explained as being bound to rise given more inflation and inflation expected. So any reluctance to act on interest rates would have had the Bank accused of being soft on inflation – so undermining its independent inflation-fighting credentials. An essential distinction that needs to be made by the Bank is about the different forces that can drive prices higher. The difference between prices that rise because less is being supplied to the economy, and prices that increase in response to higher levels of demand that run ahead of potential supplies, call for very different monetary policy reactions. It is a vital distinction about inflation that the Reserve Bank very self-consciously has refused to acknowledge.

Inflation in SA has accelerated in recent years mostly because of the supply side shocks to supplies of goods and services and the higher prices that have followed. Exchange rate shocks have caused prices to rise independently of the state of domestic demand, as has the drought that reduced the local supply of essential foodstuffs. These inevitably higher prices have further discouraged demand. Adding higher interest rates to the mixture then depresses demand even further, without seemingly doing much at all to restrain the upward march of the CPI.

What the SA economy deserved and didn’t get from the Reserve Bank was a very different narrative, one that can explain why interest rates do not have to rise irrespective of the forces driving prices higher. That excess demand justifies higher interest rates; reduced supplies do not. And therefore why sacrificing growth, for no less inflation realised, is not good monetary policy. 22 July 2016

Monetary policy: Thanks for the small relief

The Reserve Bank, thankfully and understandably, given the near recession state of the economy, decided not to raise its repo rate at its meeting last week. The Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) statement concluded that:

“The increase in the repo rate at the previous MPC meeting contributed to the improvement in the longer-term inflation forecast, and that move should be seen in conjunction with previous actions in the cycle and the lagged effects of monetary policy. The MPC felt that there is some room to pause in this tightening cycle and accordingly decided to keep the repurchase rate unchanged for now at 7,0 per cent per annum. Five members preferred no change, while one member preferred a 25 basis point increase.

“The MPC remains focused on its inflation mandate, but sensitive to the extent possible to the state of the economy. The MPC will not hesitate to act appropriately should the inflation dynamics require a response, within a flexible inflation targeting framework. Future moves, as before, will continue to be highly data dependent.”

The MPC, as indicated, continues to regard itself as in a tightening cycle. Why further likely interest rate increases will be helpful in reducing the inflation rate any more, than past increases have done, is much less obvious. As we show below, short-term interest rates in SA have risen by 2% since the first 50bp increase in the repo rate was imposed in January 2014. Inflation, having fallen in early 2015, has recently risen sharply above 6%. A very good proxy for expected inflation – inflation compensation in the bond market, being the difference between the yield on a vanilla RSA 10-year bond and its inflation-protected equivalent – also rose sharply in late 2015, as did the difference between RSA 10-year bond yields and US Treasuries of the same duration. This difference may be regarded as the average annual rate at which the rand is expected to depreciate against the US dollar over the next 10 years.

These unfortunate trends have occurred despite higher interest rates and despite a weaker economy, to which higher interest rates have undoubtedly contributed. According to the Reserve Bank forecasting model, every one percentage point increase in the repo rate reduces the GDP growth rates by 0.4% p.a. and the inflation rate by 0.3% over the subsequent 12 months. To put such predicted reactions in some perspective, this means that to reduce the inflation rate by one and a half percent from 6.5% (above the target range of 3% to 6%) to 5%, it would take a five percentage point increase in short term interest rates. Interest rate increases that would be predicted to reduce GDP growth rates by two percentage points, say from plus one to minus one. This is a high price to pay in foregone output and incomes it must be agreed for still high inflation.

The increases in short rates to date will have reduced already anemic GDP growth rates by close to one percentage point. But such outcomes presume that all other influences on the inflation rate and on GDP growth included in the forecasting model will have remained as predicted by the assumptions and feedback loops of the model – a very unlikely outcome indeed, as recent experience will have demonstrated.

The recent increase in the inflation rate owes a great deal to rising food prices- the delayed impact of the drought that so reduced the maize, wheat and other harvests. The much weaker rand and higher administered prices, especially electricity charges, would have added to the pressures on costs and prices. But the pass through effect of a weaker rand on imported inflation and so the CPI, was unusually muted in 2015 given lower oil and commodity prices. Weakness in emerging markets and emerging market (EM) currencies in response to weaker EM growth and less risk tolerance in global capital markets however meant a weaker rand that depreciated against a stronger USD, broadly in line with the other EM currencies. But the events that moved the rand and inflationary expectations higher and added materially to SA risk, and to a still weaker rand expected over the next 10 years, were very South African in origin. President Jacob Zuma’s intervention in SA’s financial affairs was unprecedented and unpredictable. It did much damage to the annual inflation and exchange rate outlook – adding about 2% p.a more to both – such that increases in interest rates, even very significant increases, would not have countered and cannot be expected to counter. Yet they would have damaged the real economy in the predicted way.

The outlook for inflation will continue to be dominated by forces well beyond the influence of Reserve Bank interest rates, making inflation forecasts an unreliable exercise. Politics, the weather and global forces, including degrees of risk aversion accompanying commodity price trends, will be as decisive as they have been to date. Raising interest rates in such circumstances can have only one fairly predictable outcome: to slow down the economy further so making a credit ratings downgrade more likely.

The only justification for ever raising interest rates aggressively in SA would be when aggregate demand is rising strongly enough to put upward pressure on prices. Such pressure on prices will however then be accompanied by strong growth, not the weak growth now experienced. If the economy were growing well, say at a 5% rate and inflation was rising at above target rates, say at 6.5% p.a, then raising interest rates by say 300bp over a 24 month period could make every sense. Inflation could then be expected to come down to below six per cent and growth could slow down to a still satisfactory 4% or so rate.

The distinction between demand side forces acting on inflation that would justify higher interest rates and supply side shocks that drive the inflation rate temporarily higher and simultaneously but reduce demand and growth rates, is an essential one to make. Supply side shocks on prices should be ignored by monetary policy: this is the conventional wisdom. It is a distinction between supply side and demand side-driven higher prices that the Reserve Bank refuses to make. It has cost the economy dearly, while inflation and inflation expected have accelerated for reasons that have had little to do with the Reserve Bank. As I have said before, monetary policy in SA needs a better narrative, one that will preserve the credibility of the Reserve Bank without it having to play King Canute.

Incidentally, if the most recent forecasts of the Reserve Bank for inflation (below target in 2018) and GDP growth (no more than 1.7% in 2018) turn out to be accurate, the case for raising interest rates and any extension of a tightening cycle will remain as weak as it is now. Here’s hoping for better weather, conservative fiscal policy settings and a credible Minister of Finance, and a stable or stronger rand, enough to reverse inflation trends and lead interest rates lower- an essential condition for a cyclical recovery.

Why accurately measuring and anticipating inflation is much more than a statistical exercise

Tim Harford of the Financial Times in an article carried in Business Day 18th May (Big data power up inflation figures) writes of the attempts under way to predict inflation ahead of the official data releases using ‘big data” – in this case observing continuously thousands even billions of prices reported online “by hundreds of retailers in more than 60 countries”

There is however more to this very welcome exercise made possible by modern technology than improving our measures of inflation –or being better able to adjust prices for changes in the quality of the goods and service being priced in the market place- a truly formidable task as Harford suggests. Or for that matter in the practice of in using high frequency data to predict the next GDP announcement, which also comes with something of a time lag. Helping to anticipate the next GDP announcement in the US is an exercise undertaken by one of the branches of the Fed. The Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta publishes its GDPNow forecasts of GDP that are attracting understandable attention in financial markets.

The primary purpose in being able to more accurately predicting inflation or growth announcements to come is that it helps the forecaster to anticipate central bank policy changes – in the form of interest rate adjustments or doses of money creation- now called Quantitative Easing- that may follow the news about inflation or growth. Past performance tells us that central banks will react in predictable ways to the unexpected, to the surprisingly good or bad economic news to which inflation and GDP announcements make a large contribution. The economic news is important because the central bank regards the news as important. They are mandated to meet targets for price stability and to help the economy realise its growth potential. Knowing what the central bank will do can be very valuable information. Valuable because what central banks can do is move markets. And beating the market- being ahead of the market moves – can be extraordinarily valuable. Just as being behind the new direction of a market can be as damaging to participants in markets who miss-read the signals.

Central banks however can only move the markets in what they may regard as the right directions if they can take the market place by surprise. As is well recognized in the market place- only surprising news matters- the expected is captured in current prices and valuations. And so there is every reason for participants in the financial markets not to be surprised so that they can take evasive action in good time and position themselves for what central banks and the market may do to them. Better forecasting models of inflation or growth – or even of the next inflation or GDP announcements, using new technology- big data- helps market participants to realize profits or avoid losses.

Yet by anticipating central bank action the market place helps void the intended influence of central bank actions on the economy. This makes central banks much less influential over the economy than the still generally accepted conventions allow central bankers about the role they can and should play in managing the business cycle. Robert Lucas of Chicago in 1995 was awarded a Nobel Prize in economics (as were other rational expectation theorists, for this “policy invariance” critique of central banks, including Finn Kydland and Edward Prescott (2004) And one could add to this list of path breaking Nobel Prize winning economists, Edmund Phelps (2006) and even Milton Friedman (1976) honoured for demonstrating that economic growth could not be stimulated by inflation. They showed that any favourable trade-offs of inflation (bad) for more growth (good) were between unexpected inflation (not inflation) and GDP growth- something very difficult to achieve in any consistent way because of inflation avoiding behaviour market participants would be bound to take. The case for more inflation had been made by the famous Phillips curve- a theory that at one stage enjoyed wide support in the economics profession as a justification for engineering more inflation. Inflation (higher prices) it was thought could help overcome price and wage rigidities that were presumed to prevent an economy finding its own path to full employment. It became the essence of Keynesian economics.

Modern central bankers now take inflationary expectations very seriously. So labelled Expected inflation augmented Phillips curves are at the heart of their inflation modelling. (Inappropriately given the history of a failed theory) They attempt through their policy interventions to “anchor” inflationary expectations- as the phrase goes. By anchoring inflationary expectations they hope to avoid inflationary surprises that are well understood to be damaging to the real economy.

Unexpectedly high or low inflation makes it harder for firms and trade unions, with price and wage setting power to make the right output and employment optimizing decisions about wages and prices. Unexpectedly high or low inflation can temporarily confuse them about the true state of the economy and so exaggerate the direction of the business cycle that will in time be reversed as inflation expected adjusts to actual inflation.

But this sensible understanding of the need to avoid inflation surprises does not seem to inhibit the larger ambitions of central banks to manage the business cycle. They still seem to believe that they able to helpfully “fine tune” the economy- manage the business cycle – through appropriate changes in interest rates and QE so that the economy can realizes its full growth potential. But logically or rather illogically this must mean being able to surprise the market place with their policy reactions – a market that is very determined not to be surprised.

In pursuing such grand ambitions to manage more than inflationary expectations, central bankers are perhaps promising more than they can hope to deliver- and so attaching too much attention to themselves. The market place has become increasingly skeptical about central bank delivering on its promises to manage aggregate global spending, demand that remains deficient despite the best efforts of central bankers world-wide. More central bank modesty – as well as more realism in the market place – about what central bankers can and cannot do – is called for.

Monetary policy in SA – the dangers of bad theory put into practice

The Reserve Bank is well aware that there are no demand side upward pressures on the inflation rate. In fact the opposite is very much the case. Weak demand is clearly constraining the power that sellers have to increase prices, not only in South Africa but globally. Hence for inflation forecasters, including those at the Bank, lower rather than higher than expected inflation.

Moreover, the price increases to come from Eskom and municipalities and perhaps also the Government (higher tax rates) can be expected to not only add to the CPI but deflate household spending even further in the months to come. But regardless of even slower growth to come, the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) decided on a 4-2 count that a further sacrifice of expected growth was called for.

To quote the concluding remarks of its statement of 19 November:

“In the absence of demand pressures, the MPC had to decide whether to act now or later. On the one hand, given the relative stability in the underlying core inflation, delaying the adjustment could give the MPC room to re-assess these unfolding developments at the next meeting, and avoid possible additional headwinds to the weak growth outlook. On the other hand, delaying the adjustment further could lead to second-round effects and require an even stronger monetary policy response in the future, with more severe consequences for short-term growth.

“Complicating the decision was the deteriorating economic growth outlook. Although the change to the growth forecast was marginal, the risks to the outlook, which were more or less balanced at the previous meeting, are now assessed to be on the downside. Against this difficult backdrop, the MPC decided to increase the repurchase rate by 25 basis points to 6,25 per cent per annum effective from 20 November 2015. Four members preferred an increase, while two members favoured an unchanged stance. “
The Reserve Bank has again been guided by a theory of dubious logic and unbacked by evidence that inflation expected in SA can drive inflation ever higher – regardless of the state of demand in an economy. Or in other words firms and trade unions with price and wage setting power, in their budgets and plans for the future, having set their new demands on consumers and employers with expected inflation in mind – will stick to them. Stick to them, that is, and then ask for still more at the next round regardless of the ability or willingness of customers or employers to meet these demands. Without support from the demand side of the economy and highly accommodative monetary policy responses to higher expected and actual inflation, ever higher prices cannot stick, and will not stick because such behaviour is simply not consistent with income maximising behaviour. It has not done so to date and will not do so as the theory of prices, properly understood, would predict.

In simple theories of inflation used by most central banks, including the US Fed, and as explained very clearly in an important speech given by Fed Chair Yellen recently, the influence of inflationary expectations on prices – that find the way into prices asked for – are combined with and excess demand or supply variable, known as the output gap. The theory is that the wider the output gap, the less inflation – for any given inflation expected. The Reserve Bank has seen fit to deny the role of the output gap and its own already higher interest rate settings in restraining inflation. It is a peculiar monetary policy and, more important, theory of economic behaviour that is being applied by the Reserve Bank.

Furthermore, the evidence is very strong that inflation expected in SA is highly stable about the 6% level and is likely to remain so – if and when inflation in SA trends lower. It can and should do so if the rand strengthens – a force largely beyond Reserve Bank powers or powers to predict. Inflation leads inflation expected in SA, as it did between 2003 and 2006 when, thanks to a strong recovery in the rand, inflation receded and inflation expected followed.

We can only hope for a further episode of rand recovery, lower rates of inflation in SA to follow and less inflation expected as measured by the gap between conventional and inflation linked bond yields. If this should happen then the theory of inflation being driven by the mere thought of more inflation will be thoroughly and most helpfully disabused – as it should be.

As it happened on Thursday 19 November, the chances of this test of the theory improved for reasons, surely completely independently of the Reserve Bank decision that was taken at about 15h30 our time. As Bloomberg shows (see figures below) almost exactly at that time the MPC announced higher short term rates for SA, long term interest rates in the US fell quite sharply and long term rates in SA followed lower. A surprising combination of higher short term rates in SA and lower long term rates was to be observed. Also to be observed was a stronger rand. Again, this was caused by forces quite beyond Reserve Bank influence. Emerging equity markets enjoyed a nice bounce higher – consistently combined with the lower interest rates in the US – and even more consistently combined with a firmer rand. Clearly the fear of a Fed rate hike has been well priced into markets: the Fed decision to raise rates in December has become much more certain fact and its impact much less disturbing.

This confirms once more that the most important influence on inflation, the behaviour of the rand, is largely beyond the influence of short term interest rates in SA. Therefore the Reserve Bank can in practice only hope to influence the level of demand in SA, which it does consistently by raising or lowering interest rates. Given weak demand and the absence of demand side pressures on prices in SA, it should be lowering, not raising its repo rate. The Reserve Bank is relying on a theory that inflation in SA could become self-fulfilling and therefore demands higher interest rates, doing our economy a grave disservice in the process.

 

Global rates: The dropping of the shoe

The reactions of the Fed. The other shoe has dropped – thankfully for those living downstairs.

The first Fed shoe dropped in May 2013 when it announced it would soon be halting, or in its own words “tapering” QE, that is the purchase by the Fed of US government bonds and mortgage backed paper in the market place in exchange for its own deposits. In other words, the Fed signaled its intention to stop creating money, as it had been doing to the tune of an extra US$85bn a month. True to its word, by year end 2014, QE was suspended.

The reactions in the financial markets to this announcement in 2013 were quite dramatic, and especially so in emerging market (EM) equity, currency and bond markets, including South Africa. The rand lost over 12% of its US dollar value within a few weeks, from about R9 to the dollar at the beginning of May 2013 to about R10 at month end while the yield on the RSA 10 year increased from 6.3% p.a to 7.08% p.a by month end. The benchmark EM equity index, the MSCI EM, lost 10% of its value between May and June 2013 while the US dollar value of the JSE All Share Index lost 6.8% in US dollars over the two months.

The second Fed shoe has now dropped, which is perhaps just as well for those who have been waiting for it to hit the floor. The second shoe comes in the form of the upward move in the Fed’s short term rates, the first such increase since the financial crisis of 2008. An increase of 25bps in US short term rates in December now seems certain, or at least the market place has reacted as if it is almost certain.

Market reaction to this news have been far more muted than the responses described as the taper tantrums of 2013. The rand has lost about three percent of its dollar exchange value since the September month end. 10 year bond yields are about 30bps higher in response to the now firm prospect of higher short rates in the US.

The shoe having dropped, is there more damage in prospect for the rand and the borrowing costs of the SA government? The answer will depend largely on ongoing investor sentiment towards emerging markets. Higher interest rates in the US and elsewhere are not welcome in hard-pressed EM economies. But confirmation that the US economy is firmly on a recovery track, is surely encouraging to all those EM businesses that trade with the US. A combination of strength in the US and less anxiety about the Chinese economy would surely be better news for EM economies and their longer term prospects that now appear so poor (as reflected in EM share markets that in US dollars are well down on their levels of September 2009, while the New York benchmark S&P 500 has been racking higher ever since).

The rand remains an EM equity currency. It continues to move in response to the US dollar value of the EM equity benchmark as we show below. South African events do not appear to affect the rand in any consistent or significant way.

The rand is little changed versus other EM currencies over recent days, though both the Turkish lira and Brazilian real have recovered some of their weakness against the rand. On a trade weighted basis, the rand, in line with other EM currency and equity markets, has weakened significantly since mid-year, though much of the damage occurred in August rather than very recently.

The rand’s daily moves can be well explained by global market developments independently of SA political or economic developments (which cannot anyway be regarded as favourable). For example, as we show below, the rand rate against the US dollar can be predicted to closely follow trends in the US dollar / Australian dollar exchange rate, coupled with a measure of SA sovereign risk. Sovereign risk is measured as the premium investors would pay to ensure against SA government default on its debt. The results of such a model are shown below. It suggests that the rand, now trading at over R14 to the US dollar, has overshot its predicted value of R13.50 or so.

We get a similar result and a similarly satisfactory model of the rand when we replace the influence of the Australian dollar with the MSCI EM and combine this with the credit default spread on US dollar-denominated SA debt. The rand appears somewhat oversold using these models.

It is also clear that as the prospect of higher US rates has become more certain, the risks associated with EM debt, as measured by the spreads over US government debt, have also increased. The spreads attached to SA debt have widened largely in line with EM spreads generally. SA specific risks do not appear to have had a significant influence on these spreads recently. Higher spreads and higher interest rates in SA appear mostly as an EM rather than SA event. The Credit Default Swap (CDS) spread between SA dollar-denominated debt and the average EM (Brady Bond) spread has not altered recently. In a relative sense, SA debt lost some rating ground versus other EM borrowers by mid-year, however. The spread in favour of SA can be seen to have narrowed.

Long term interest rates in SA have followed modestly higher rates in the US as the near certain increase in short rates was priced into the debt markets. As we have mentioned, these increases can be regarded as modest to date.

The wider EM risk spreads have not led to any exaggerated movements in the yields on rand-denominated RSA debt. We must hope that the very little inflation expected in the US helps to continue to restrain the Fed from ratcheting up short rates and that long term rates in the US remain at historically low levels for an extended period of time. We expect very dovish Fed reactions, especially given the stronger dollar that will keep down the pressure on metal and mineral prices and make deflation rather than inflation the focus of Fed concerns.

Less upward pressure from US interest rates on SA rates (short and long) will be helpful for the rand and the inflation outlook in SA. Hopefully, less pressure will restrain the Reserve Bank from even thinking about higher interest rates. Higher rates in SA would not necessarily protect the rand should the dollar get stronger with higher rates in the US.

The other shoe – in the form of market reactions to higher interest rates in the US – may well have dropped. And the reactions in the market place to date reflect a much more relaxed response to the prospect of higher rates in the US than was the case in 2013. We must hope and encourage the Reserve Bank to also keep its composure.

How well is the equity market reading the Fed?

 

The Fed made one thing very clear on Thursday after it decided to leave its interest rates unchanged: short term interest rates in the US will stay lower for longer than previously forecast. The equity markets responded favourably to the news for about an hour and then changed their collective mind. A sense that the Fed explanation – of its lack of action implied lower rates of economic growth – soon overcame what might have been a favourable influence on share prices. Other things equal, lower interest rates mean higher share prices. But other things are seldom equal when central banks react, as the market has again revealed.

While equity indexes fell away, the responses in the other sectors of the capital markets were very obviously consistent with a shallower expected rising path for short term interest rates in the US. Longer term interest rates declined quite sharply almost everywhere, including in South Africa, and the dollar lost ground against almost all other currencies, including most emerging market currencies like the rand.

Interest rates have causes as well as effects. If the cause is lower than previously forecast growth rates, the expected impact on the top line of any present value calculation – a lesser expected flow of revenue and operating profits – can outweigh the influence of a lower rate at which such profits are to be discounted. This seems to characterise recent global equity market reactions. Could the market change this initially negative interpretation of Fed policy for equity values?

We think it could – because the Fed has (surprisingly) explicitly accepted its responsibilities to the global and not only the US economy. That the Fed has recognised that the strong US economy, leading to a mighty US dollar, has left strains in its wake. The Fed reacting to these strains seems to us to improve the prospects for global economic growth by moderating some of the risks to the global economy linked to the strong dollar. Furthermore, from now on any failure of the Fed to raise rates does not imply any unexpected weakness in the US economy – rather it will be the global economy that will be the focus of attention.

The disturbances to global equity and currency markets in late August emanated from China. What the Chinese were thought to be doing and intended to do to the still undeveloped market in the renminbi rattled the markets. The threat of a competitive devaluation of the yuan, whose rate of exchange was firmly linked to the very strong dollar, would be a clear danger to the global economy.

The Japanese yen and the euro, the most important competitors and customers for China, had both devalued significantly versus the dollar and the yuan without any obvious push back from the US or China. Competitive devaluations and beggar-thy-neighbour policies did grave damage to the global economy in the 1930s by decimating the volume of international trade. All economies gain from trade, buying more from and selling more to other economies and raising their efficiencies accordingly. Any threat to global trade is a threat to growth. China was perceived to be such a threat even as the Chinese authorities were doing all they could to convince the markets that they could and would support the yuan against weakness.

The weaker dollar and a globally sensitive Fed surely diminish the risks that the Chinese will make policy errors that the rest of the world will suffer from. It takes off some of the deflationary pressure on commodities and commodity currencies. It also reduces some of the burden of dollar denominated debts incurred by emerging market companies and governments. A weaker dollar is also helpful for the reported earnings of US business with global operations. The willingness of the Fed to react to global and not only US economic developments. This enhanced sensitivity of the Fed to the state of the global economy should therefore be welcomed by shareholders everywhere.

It should also help to relax central bankers outside of the US, not least those in Pretoria, who have seemed particularly agitated by the prospect of rising rates in the US. The case for lowering short term rates in SA to promote much needed additional spending has improved – as it has improved everywhere. This is good news for shareholders

An avoidable trade off

Less growth for no less inflation: a trade off that could have been avoided with lower, not higher, interest rates

Since the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) of the Reserve Bank decided to raise its repo rate by 0.25 percentage points on Thursday, the outlook for SA growth has deteriorated, because of the likely impact of higher interest rates on spending; while the outlook for inflation has deteriorated, because the rand has weakened. Less growth for more inflation hardly seems like a useful tradeoff, but that is what the SA economy has to confront.

Can we however blame the Reserve Bank for the weaker rand? We can, if the prospect of slower growth is expected to reduce the case for investing in SA and therefore is associated with the weaker rand. But the rand may have weakened for other reasons unrelated to the Reserve Bank decision. Emerging market risks may have simultaneously increased, thus discouraging capital inflows, or something the MPC also worries about – interest rates in the US may increase, so driving capital away from emerging markets leading to a weaker rand.

Neither of these forces since Thursday last week can explain the fact that the rand lost a little ground to other emerging market currencies, while interest rates in the US fell rather than rose. Moreover, while long term rates in SA remained little changed, the spread between RSA and US rates widened since the interest rate increase, indicating an increase in the SA risk premium (a wider spread is usually associated with rand weakness).

Furthermore short term rates – up to one year duration – all rose in tandem after the MPC meeting, indicating that the outlook for interest rates to come has not changed in response to Reserve Bank action or explanation. The interest rate carry in favour of the rand, AKA the SA risk premium, remains as it was. The forward looking stance of monetary policy, in the collective view of the money market, has therefore not softened – a softening that might have served to explain the weaker rand, but does not.

All of this indicates another point we have made repeatedly. The impact of any move in policy-determined SA interest rates on the exchange value of the rand is essentially unpredictable. This makes the relationship between interest rate changes and inflation also highly unpredictable, so undermining the logic of inflation targets. Inflation targets, if they are to be met with interest rate settings, demand a predictable relationship between interest rate movements and inflation itself. This predictability does not exist.

The unpredictable reactions in the currency markets help vitiate the presumption that interest rates can be a useful instrument for realising inflation targets. Upredictable increases in administered prices, the price of electricity, water, municipal services etc. that may drive inflation temporarily higher (as might a weaker maize harvest) are supply side forces that do not respond to higher interest rates. The notion that interest rates should rise in response to an economically damaging drought is surely risible. Higher interest rates in SA do have one highly predictable effect and that is to reduce spending.

The latest surprise for the inflation forecasting model of the Reserve Bank from which interest rate settings take their cue, is that the so called pass through effect from a weaker rand to higher prices is about half as strong as predicted by the model. Both the rand prices of imports (helpfully) and exports (unhelpfully for the domestic economy) are lower than they were a year ago, reducing rather than adding to the pressure on the CPI. This time round it is not the weaker rand that can be blamed for higher inflation to date- but a still weaker rand clearly imposes the risk of more inflation to come.

The MPC, by increasing short term interest rates, willingly added to the risks of still lower growth rates. Our view is that this represents a distinct error of judgment.

To quote the MPC statement:

“The MPC has indicated for some time that it is in a hiking cycle in response to rising inflation risks, and a normalisation of the policy rate over time. The MPC is cognisant of the fact that domestic inflation is not driven by demand factors, and the outlook for household consumption expenditure remains subdued. Economic growth remains subdued, constrained by electricity supply disruptions and low business and consumer confidence and the risks to the outlook remain on the downside. However, as emphasised previously, we have to be mindful of the risk of second-round effects on inflation, and the committee is concerned that failure to act against these heightened pressures and risks will cause inflation expectations to become entrenched at higher levels.”

We would take issue with the relevance of the so defined second round effects that is so important to the Reserve Bank view of how inflation comes about. That is the notion that more inflation expected can lead to more inflation as a kind of self fulfilling process and that it takes, if necessary, painfully higher interest rates to control such expectations. The reality, in our view, is that these inflation expectations held in SA are particularly well entrenched and highly stable at around the 6% level, the upper end of the inflation target band. That is, if we infer inflation expected from the actions of investors in the bond market, being the difference in yields offered by vanilla bonds and their inflation protected alternatives of similar duration. These differences are shown below for 10 year bond yields.

Thus, the remarkable fact about the extra rewards for taking on inflation risk – the difference between a coupon exposed to unexpected inflation and one completely protected against actual inflation – I is how stable it has been, around about 6%, the period of the global financial crisis in 2008 excluded. The daily average spread since 2009 has been 5.95%, with a maximum yield spread of 6.92% and a minimum of 4.55%, with a Standard Deviation of 0.41%. It would seem to us that the inflation leads inflation expected – not the other way round- and that it would take an extended period of inflation well below 6% p.a to reduce inflation expected. These second round effects are a theory without empirical support that is preventing monetary policy from acting in a usefully counter cyclical way. A cycle that calls for lower not higher interest rates to encourage not discourage growth that attracts capital and might support not weaken the rand.

Furthermore, the MPC should recognise that price setters, that is most firms, set prices according to what the market will bear, that prices are not simply cost or wages plus sum pre-determined profit margin. Higher costs will lead to lower margins if demands from the market restrict pricing power, and higher wages can lead to fewer people employed in the presence of weak demand and the absence of pricing power.

In the distinct presence of weak demand, fully recognised by the MPC, neither expected inflation nor higher wages explain higher inflation in SA. Nor does money or credit growth help explain why inflation in SA is currently as high as it is. Households are borrowing very little more than they did a year ago and firms are borrowing more, but to invest abroad not locally. Money supply growth remains subdued.

Higher taxes, in the form of higher administered prices, explain much of inflation to date and help explain much of the inflation forecast by the Reserve Bank Model. Administered prices, petrol and electricity for example, are assumed to increase by 11.7% and 12.5% respectively in 2016. Yet these price increases add further to the pressure on household and business budgets and further inhibit spending. Yet the MPC seems convinced their monetary policy settings remain supportive of the economy rather than a threat to it. To quote the PMC statement further:

“The expected inflation trajectory implies that the real repurchase rate remains low and possibly still slightly negative at times, and below its longer term average. The monetary policy stance therefore remains supportive of the domestic economy. The continuing challenge is for monetary policy to achieve a fine balance between achieving our core mandate of price stability and not undermining short term growth unduly. Monetary policy actions will continue to be sensitive, to the extent possible, to the fragile state of the economy. As before, any future moves will therefore be highly data dependent.”

We must beg to differ about the measured stance of monetary policy. A prime rate of 9.25% is well ahead of the price increases most private businesses are able to charge their customers. They do not have the monopoly powers of an Eskom or a municipality to charge more regardless of the state of demand. Keeping prices rising in line with headline inflation (not of their making) is becoming much more difficult, so making monetary policy ever less supportive of the domestic economy.

The economy is fragile and higher interest rates have made it still more so. Had the Reserve Bank been more sensitive to the state of the economy and more data dependent (and not embarked on a premature path to higher interest rates) the economy would have better prospects and a stronger not weaker rand might well have reflected this.

Will the Reserve Bank prove data or path dependent?

The members of the Federal Open Markets Committee (FOMC), while contemplating an increase in their key Fed Funds rate from an abnormal zero per cent to a slightly less abnormal 0.25%, are at pains to emphasise that such decisions remain “data dependent”.

Most recently chair Janet Yellen indicated that if the data on the US economy confirm their forecasts of an economic recovery well under way, then interest rates in the US will rise this year – this after spending all the while since 2009 at about zero. One would hope that their counterparts on the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) of the SA Reserve Bank remain equally data dependent.

The danger is that the MPC has become path dependent – it has signaled its firm intention to raise rates this year regardless of the state of the SA economy, the state of which (if anything) has deteriorated in recent months as household spending on goods and services has slowed down. The MPC might believe that not raising rates (independent of data) would be interpreted as being soft on inflation – a most unfortunate state of path dependence if that becomes the case. Travelling down this path to still higher short term rates would be a grave error of judgment, even if the market place regards such interest rate developments as inevitable. The MPC needs to step off this path it has mapped out for itself.

It has to be pointed out that any further increases in its repo rate have been postponed ever since June 2014, presumably because of the weak economic data. The SA inflation to date has had nothing to do with excess demand that would usually call for restraint in the form of higher borrowing costs. Spending by firms, households and recently by the government itself (practising a degree of austerity) have grown even more slowly than even energy-repressed supply. Higher observed prices have almost everything to do with higher taxes on expenditure – on petrol and diesel and on electricity charged by Eskom and municipalities – with the prospect of further increases to come. Absent of these tax events the inflation rate would have been about the three per cent rate it reached in February 2015 – between August 2014 and February 2015 the CPI itself hardly rose at all – indicating a very subdued underlying trend in inflation before higher taxes kicked in. The firm rand in a world of deflation was a very helpful contributor to these trends. Despite the strong US dollar and because of the weak euro, with the largest weight in our foreign trade, the trade weighted rand is little changed from its exchange value 12 months ago. See below, where strength is indicated by higher numbers:

These more favourable exchange rate and demand side influences on prices in general have been well reflected Producer Price Inflation, prices charged at the factory and mine gates, that was 3% in April 2015. The mines and factories are not exercising much pricing power- the markets they serve are not proving very accommodating to higher prices they are being charged for their inputs- for tax and trade union reasons. The notion that real interest rates in SA- measured conventionally and unhelpfully as the difference between overdraft rates and CPI inflation is not a burden on producers – is belied by the fact that producers are not achieving anything like average consumer price increases in the prices they are able to charge their customers. Costs may rise, including the costs of hiring labour, but profit margins may well have to give way to economic realities, as will employment opportunities- even as may be observed – in the public sector.

The Reserve Bank would have to argue that inflation in SA would have been higher and would be higher if it did not raise its rates. Their argument is that expected inflation drives prices and inflation. The evidence for such a feedback loop from inflation expected to inflation is very unconvincing. Indeed the rate of inflation expected by the bond market has remained remarkably stable around the 6% p.a rate, the upper end of the inflation target range, indicating very little change in observed inflation could have come from that constant quarter. If anything actual inflation leads inflation expected. Inflation comes down and less is expected – inflation goes up and more inflation is priced into long term interest rates- not the other way round. See below where we show inflation compensation- the difference yields on 10 year RSA’s and their inflation linked equivalentsyields over the past 12 months. Inflation compensation moved lower with less inflation and has since moved higher as it became apparent that he receiver of revenue would tax much of the gains from lower oil prices.

The Reserve Bank must argue that without its actions and narrative, inflation expected would now be higher and inflation even higher. It is impossible to refute such a counterfactual. To know what would have happened had interest rates not been raised last year and had the Reserve Bank not suggested that further rate increases were to be expected, remains an unknown. But we would argue that there is something very wrong with a narrative that suggests interest rates must rise regardless of the state of the economy, especially if it cannot be known with any degree of confidence, that higher interest rates can reliably influence the rate of inflation itself.

The link between higher interest rates and the exchange value of the rand and therefore on inflation to come, is particularly difficult to establish, given all the other influences on the rand. Especially the impact on emerging market currencies generally of a highly variable and unpredictable global taste for risk and so the flows into emerging market equities and bonds and their currencies. However it can be predicted, with a much higher degree of confidence, that higher rates will depress domestic demand and GDP growth rates. As the rating agencies constantly remind us, the biggest risk to SA and its credit rating is slow growth. Sacrificing growth for whatever reason is a risky strategy, especially if its impact on inflation is unpredictable. In fact stronger growth can lead to less inflation if growth attracts foreign capital and supports the rand. And vice versa when the prospect of slower growth drives capital away from SA and weakens the rand

The major uncertainty facing the markets in the near future will be the reaction to the Fed rate increase. The impact of this widely expected move on emerging market currencies will be very hard to predict with accuracy. In the past, rising US rates that accompanied faster US growth rates have usually had a favourable impact on emerging markets. This is because US growth implies faster global growth, from which emerging market economies and their financial markets and currencies stand to benefit. It makes little sense for the Reserve Bank to talk up local interest rates for fear that higher rates in the US will weaken the rand and cause inflation in SA to increase. Higher interest rates will do nothing to counter such a shock, should it occur.

The right policy response to any currency shock is to ignore it and allow exchange rate flexibility to help the economy recover from such a shock. Higher inflation that follows a supply side shock of the exchange rate or tax kind itself depresses domestic spending. Interest rate increases in such circumstances are not called for – despite higher inflation. This should be the Reserve Bank narrative, not its vain pursuit of inflation targets, regardless of the causes or consequences of inflation. Policy actions above all should be data dependent and not predetermined.

Softer tone – stronger rand. A very helpful outcome for the SA economy.

A confident newly appointed Governor adopted a dovish tone. Correctly, but to some degree surprisingly so, with the so-described “normalisation’ of interest rates postponed, perhaps for an extended period of time depending on the data, both local and, as important, foreign developments.

The bond market reacted accordingly, pushing bond prices higher and yields lower. The big surprise to the Reserve Bank was surely the behaviour of the rand: a softer tone with a stronger rand on the day, though surprising, would have been welcomed by the MPC. It improves the outlook for inflation and also the real economy that needs all the help it can get. The risks to inflation are now regarded as balanced rather than to the upside. If inflation continues to trend lower and below the upper band of the inflation target range, the case for lower short rates will present itself. This is particularly the case if the domestic economy continues to operate below potential and the global inflation and interest rate environment remains benign.

It may well remain so despite higher short rates in the US, which presents itself as the only developed economy capable of tolerating such higher interest rates. Weakness in other developed and developing economies will make for a stronger US dollar and simultaneously lower dollar prices for the key metals, minerals and staples traded on global markets. But a weaker rand / US dollar rate may be offset on the crosses and imply much less pressure on the CPI than usual – as has been the case this year.

The reaction in the currency market – less pressure on short rates combined with a stronger rand – helps illustrate an important empirical regularity. The impact of policy determined interest rate movements on the value of the rand is largely unpredictable. It has about an equal chance of going either way. Therefore raising rates may not help reduce inflation outcomes, or reducing them increase the rate of inflation to come. What is predictable is the impact of interest rates on domestic spending. Higher rates slow down spending trends and lower rates help improve them.

On Thursday (the day of the MPC meeting) the lack of pressure on short rates extended to the longer end of the bond market. Perhaps flows of funds from offshore in anticipation of declining long bond yields moved bond prices higher and the rand stronger. We show the reactions in the bond and money market below. It can happen again: less pressure on short term interest rates with the prospect of faster growth in SA can assist the rand and promote faster growth with less inflation. Such possibilities should concentrate the mind of the MPC.

Interest rates: No need for a hike

Dependence on the data – and the inflation forecasts – mean there is no case for raising the repo rate now , nor maybe for another 12 months or longer

There would seem to be no reason at all for the Reserve Bank to raise its repo rate tomorrow. Investec Securities, applying its own simulation of the Reserve Bank forecasting model, predicts that the Reserve Bank forecast of inflation will have been unchanged ahead of the MPC meeting. This simulation is for inflation to average 6.2% for 2014(largely behind us now), 5.7% in 2015 and 5.8% in 2016. Thus inflation is predicted to come in below the upper end of the target range. Continue reading Interest rates: No need for a hike

Banks and shadow banking: Out of the shadows

Should we be frightened of our banks and their shadows or should we rather learn how to deal with banking failure?

Shadow banks rather than non-bank financial intermediaries

A new description – shadow banks – has entered the financial lexicon. The term is, as we may infer, is not used in a positive context. Rather it is to alert the public to the potential dangers in shadow banks, as opposed to the presumably better regulated banks proper.

This is a use of language consistent with one of the dictionary definitions of the word:

A dominant or pervasive threat, influence, or atmosphere, especially one causing gloom, fear, doubt, or the like: They lived under the shadow of war.

Or perhaps alluding to shadowy, defined as:

1. full of shadows; dark; shady
2. resembling a shadow in faintness; vague
3. illusory or imaginary
4. mysterious or secretive: a shadowy underworld figure

 Source:  www.Dictionary.com

An older, less pejorative description of this class of financial institution or lender would have been non-bank financial intermediary or perhaps near-bank financial intermediary to describe those firms that closely resembled banks in their lending activities. Examples are mortgage lenders (once called building societies), insurance companies, pension funds, money market funds and unit trusts, all of which would have fall under the modern description, shadow banks.

 

As we show below, drawing on the March 2014 Financial Stability Report of the SA Reserve Bank, the share of SA banks in the total business of Financial Intermediation in SA has declined over the past few years while the share of other financial intermediaries (including money market funds and unit trusts) has risen consistently, also in part at the expense of pension and retirement funds

 

Source; SA Reserve Bank Financial Stability Report, March 2014

The role of financial intermediaries is to facilitate the capital providing and raising activities of economic actors, domestic and foreign. They stand between (intermediate) the providers of capital in the economic system, be they households or firms, and those raising funds, to cover (temporary) financial deficits, that is, other households and firms and government agencies needing finance. They also compete for financial custom with those providers and users of finance who might bypass the financial intermediaries completely and deal directly with each other.

Such activities may be described as disintermediation when, for example, a firm previously dependent on bank finance bypasses the banks and issues its own debt or equity in the financial markets. The subscribers to such issues may however well be other financial intermediaries, for example pension funds, in which case  it is the banks that will have been disintermediated.

 

Why banks are different from all other financial intermediaries

What then makes banks different in principle from other financial intermediaries? It may be in the detailed manner in which they are regulated, as we indicate above. But pension and retirement funds are also subject to particular regulations and regulators designed to protect providers of capital to them as are the managers of money market funds or unit trusts.

Banks are different not because they borrow and lend (or, more generally, raise and provide capital); they are different fundamentally because an important part of their function is to provide, via some of the deposit liabilities they raise, an alternative to the cash provided by the central bank that can be used for transactions, in the older terminology, as a much more convenient medium of exchange . In so doing, they provide an essential service to the economy, providing a payment system without which the modern economy would founder.

 

The danger with banks, narrowly confined to those few institutions that provide the payments mechanism, is that a large bank failure would bring down the payments mechanism with it. This is a danger to the broader economy almost too ghastly to contemplate. It is a danger that makes a large transaction clearing bank, on which all other financial institutions depend, not only to hold their cash, but more importantly, to help make payments, too big to fail. If such a bank were in danger of failing and unable to recapitalise itself in the market place, it would be obliged to call on the taxpayer for additional capital and the central bank for cash as a lender of last resort. A call that the central bank and the government could not, in good sense, resist. Shareholders given such a rescue should then lose all they have invested in the bank while depositors might be saved while bank creditors generally may or may not be obliged to accept a haircut. A possible haircut would help bank creditors exercise essential disciplines over banks as borrowers. The moral hazard of too big to fail and therefore too big to have to worry about default could be overcome without jeopardising the payments system with a predictable well recognised set of bankruptcy procedures for banks.

 

Clearly, facilitating payments by transferring deposits on demand of their depositors, is not all that banks do. Not all their funding is by way of deposits that may be transferred or withdrawn on demand. Term deposits as well as ordinary debt may be more important on their balance sheets than current accounts or transaction balances.

 

Banks, narrowly defined as the providers of a payments system, largely originated by offering an alternative medium of exchange to that of transferring gold or silver and the notes issued by a central banks to settle obligations. The owners of banks came to realise that they did not have to maintain anything like a 100% backing in gold or notes or deposits with the central banks for the deposits that could be withdrawn without notice, to survive profitably.

 

Fractional reserve banking was seen to be possible and profitable. In other words, the interest spread between the cost of raising deposits, with demand deposits paying the lowest interest or no interest at all, helped the banks make profits on the spread between their borrowing costs and interest income and so helped pay for the costs of maintaining the payments mechanism – a form of cross subsidy. It may be surmised that had the banks had to levy fees to cover all the costs, including a return on capital, of providing the payments mechanism, bank deposits might have proved less attractive and the growth of retail banks accordingly more inhibited than it was.

 

Banks in SA have become more dependent on net interest income in recent years, rising from about 5% to 10% of net income, while operating expenses have grown by about the same percentage. Return on equity has declined but remains a respectable 15% p.a.

Source; SA Reserve Bank Financial Stability Report, March 2014

 

The inevitable risks in fractional reserve banking and leveraged banks

Such fractional reserves however do pose a risk to the shareholders of banks as well as to their depositors. There might be a run on the bank that could cause the bank to fail, making the shares they owned in the bank valueless. Clearly, the interest earning assets it typically held could not be cashed in as easily as its deposit liabilities. Banking failures led to responses by regulators – firstly in the form of a compulsory cash to deposit ratio demanded of banks and in the form of deposit insurance designed to protect the smaller depositor. This was introduced in the US in the 1930s in response to the Great Depression and the banking failures associated with it.

Compared to most other financial institutions, including the so-called shadow banks, banks proper have always been among the most highly leveraged of business enterprises.. Their debts include all deposits, current and time deposits, equivalent to 90% or more of their assets, leaving little room for errors in the loans made.

The protection provided to depositors in the form of required cash or liquid asset reserves could not insure any bank or financial institution against the bad loans that could wipe out shareholders equity and cause a bank to go out of business.  Hence the regulatory focus in recent years, not so much on cash adequacy, but on equity capital adequacy. The Basel rules promoted by the central bankers’ central bank, the Bank for International Settlements located in Basel, Switzerland, have imposed higher equity capital ratios of banks.

Understandably, the SA Reserve Bank as the regulator of the SA banks has given attention in its Financial Stability Report to the capital adequacy as well as the operating character of the banks under their supervision. The results of this analysis indicate that by international standards, the four large SA banks are well capitalised and well managed. As the table below shows, a capital to asset ratio of nearly 15% provides a return on banking shareholders’ equity of close to 15%, even though the return on total assets held by the banks is only 1.1%. Without high degrees of leverage SA banks might not be profitable enough to be willing to cross-subsidise the payments mechanism. If so other providers of a payments mechanism would then have to be found.

Funding such alternative providers with fees charged might not seem an attractive alternative to the current banking system that facilitates payments, partly through the interest spread, but with the danger than banks can fail. Dealing with the possibility of failure may well prove a better approach than imposing capital and cash requirements of banks that make them unable to easily stay in business.

There are no guarantees against banking failure

 

There is no guarantee that regulated bank capital, adequate for normal times and not so demanding as to threaten the profitability of banks and their survival as business enterprises, would be sufficient to support the banks in abnormal times. The global financial crisis of 2008 took place in most unusual circumstances, that is when the an average house price in the US declined by as much as 30% from peak to trough. Such declines meant that much of the mortgage lending of US banks had to be written off. Even a capital adequacy ratio of 15% might not protect a banking system, with a typically large dependence on mortgage lending, against failure, should the security in house prices collapse as they did in the US. SA banks have held up to 50% of all their assets in the form of nominally secure mortgage loans. They too would not have survived a collapse in house prices of similar magnitude.

 

Is it possible to insulate the payments mechanism from other banking activity? And what would it cost the holders of transaction balances?

 

It may be possible, given modern technology, to separate the payments system from  bank lending and borrowing. The payments system could be conceivably managed by the specialised equivalents of a credit card company that would compete for non interest bearing transactions balances on a fee only basis. The transfer mechanism could well be a smart phone or some equivalent device.

 

The proviso would have to be 100% reserve backing for these balances held for clients to transfer. These reserves that would fully cover the liability would have to take the form of a cash deposit with the central bank or notes held in the ATMs.  A deposit with a private bank would not be sufficient to the purpose- the other private bank, unlike a central bank can also fail and so bring down the payments system. If such a separation of banking from payments was enforced by regulation, large banks might not then be too big to fail any more than any other financial intermediary or indeed any other business enterprise might be regarded as too big to fail. But the unsubsidised transaction fees that would have to be levied to cover the costs of such an independent  payments system, fully protected against failure, that would include an appropriate return on shareholders capital invested in such payment companies, might prove more onerous than the costs of maintaining transaction balances with the banks today that provide a bundle of services, including facilitating transactions.

 

It is striking how expensive it is to transfer cash through the specialised agencies that provide a pure money transfer service. A fee of 5% or more of the value of such a transaction is not unusual. The case for bundling banking services, even should banks need to be recapitalised should they fail in unusual circumstances, may well be a price worth paying. In other words what is required for financial stability and a low cost payments service is a predictable rescue service for the few large banks that manage the payments system.

 

 

 

 

 

Avoiding the mind games

The MPC voted to keep interest rates on hold. Without a recovery in growth rates, interest rates will stay on hold – absent the dangerous mind games of January 2014 that led to an ill-timed rise in the repo rate.

The Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) of the Reserve Bank yesterday indicated that its outlook for SA inflation over the next few years has improved marginally. To quote the statement:

“The Bank’s forecast of headline inflation changed marginally since the previous meeting. Inflation is expected to average 6,2 per cent in 2014, compared with 6,3 per cent previously, with the peak of 6,5 per cent (previously 6,6 per cent) expected in the fourth quarter. The forecast average inflation for 2015 remained unchanged at 5,8 per cent. The forecast horizon has been extended and inflation is expected to average 5,5 per cent in 2016, and 5,4 per cent in the final quarter of that year. Inflation is still expected to remain outside the target band from the second quarter of 2014 until the second quarter of 2015.”

It also reported that inflation expectations are unchanged:

“The Reuters survey of inflation expectations of economic analysts conducted in May is more or less unchanged since the previous survey. Inflation is expected to average 6,3 per cent in the second quarter, and 6,2 per cent in the final two quarters of this year, before returning to within the target at an average of 5,8 per cent in the first quarter of 2015. Annual inflation is expected to average 6,2 per cent in 2014, and 5,6 per cent and 5,4 per cent in the subsequent two years respectively, somewhat lower than the Bank’s forecast.”

The growth outlook for the economy, according to the MPC by strong contrast has “deteriorated markedly” :

“The domestic economic growth outlook has deteriorated markedly, with the reversal of a number of the tentative positive signs observed at the beginning of the year. The Bank’s forecast for economic growth for 2014 has been revised down from 2,6 per cent at the previous meeting to 2,1 per cent, implying a further widening of the negative output gap. The forecast for 2015 remains unchanged at 3,1 per cent, and growth in 2016 is expected to average 3,4 per cent. However, the risks to these forecasts are increasingly to the downside against the renewed possibility of electricity load-shedding, among other factors.”

With this backdrop one might have thought that the decision not to raise short term interest rates would have been a formality. But not so for two members of the MPC – compared to the three at the meeting before – who actually voted for a further increase in rates. What can be on their minds?

It can’t be a belief that higher interest rates can do much to slow down inflation. The Investec Securities simulation for the Reserve Bank model of inflation and growth indicates that an increase of 25bps in the repo rate will only reduce its expected inflation by roughly 8bps and this would take seven quarters to take full effect. In other words, not much help on the inflation front at considerable further risk to the state of the economy – and moreover in the knowledge that an unpredictable exchange rate (that the model treats as an independent influence, about which assumptions rather than predictions are made when running the model).

The hard pressed SA economy had some good luck in the form of a stronger rand and a bumper maize harvest, which will help to hold down inflation in the months ahead. One gains an impression that had the rains not come when they did, the case for raising rates might have had more support.

That monetary policy is hostage to such obvious supply side shocks as drought and global risk aversion is not a comfortable thought. The reality is that inflation n SA has very little to do with the demand side of the economy (as the Reserve Bank acknowledges fully) and everything to do with factors over which interest rates have little influence: exchange rates and the harvest as well as the pace of administered price increases, which is the province of the regulators and the tax collectors.

At least this time round, at the media briefing and Q&A, the Governor was asked some leading questions about supply side effects and the influence of interest rates. She was even asked if the hike in rates in January (with hindsight surely a mistake) did any harm to the economy. There was little mea culpa in the response and a resort in the response to the non-testable theory that had the Bank not raised rates then second round effects – higher inflationary expectations – would have taken inflation higher. In fact there is no evidence that inflation expectations lead inflation rather than the other way round. And, as the MPC indicated, inflation expectations remain unchanged and the great constant in the economic environment.

This Q&A unfortunately indicates the danger in monetary policy: that members of the MPC come to believe that in order to preserve their inflation fighting credentials, and because the markets may expect them to raise interest rates, then that is what they have to do. This is regardless of the predicted outcomes for inflation and, more importantly, for growth.

The trouble with such monetary policy reactions is that they can never be tested or refuted. The economic caravan always moves on even as the dogs bark. Who can say with certainy what might have happened if the Bank had acted differently? Such mind games do not serve the SA economy well. Interest rates in SA should have been lower, not higher, given the state of the economy over the past 12 months The time for a cyclical upswing in interest rates is when the economy can justify it – not before. And there is clearly no justification for higher interest rates given the growth outlook.

Bernanke’s legacy: The great (and ongoing) monetary experiment

Ben Bernanke has now retired as Fed chairman, having rewritten the book on central banking.

He has done this not so much by what he and his fellow governors (including his successor Janet Yellen) did to address the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) that erupted in 2008, but by the enormous scale to which he supplied cash to the US and global financial system as well as in injecting new capital to shore up financial institutions whose failure would pose a risk to the financial system.

The scale of Fed interventions in the financial markets is indicated in the figure below which highlights the explosive growth in the asset side of its balance sheet. The initial actions taken after the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008, what may be regarded as classical central bank assistance for a financial system in a crisis of liquidity, was superseded by further massive injections of cash into the US and global financial system as the figure makes clear. The cash made available by the central bank in exchange for securities supplied (discounted) by hard pressed banks, when only cash would satisfy depositors and other lenders to banks, alleviated the panic and allowed normally sound financial institutions to escape the run for cash. But Quantitiative Easing (QE) thereafter became much more than a temporary help to the financial system.


Chairman Bernanke recently took the opportunity to explain his actions and the reasoning behind them in a valedictory address to his own tribe (that of professional economists) gathered at the annual meeting of the American Economic Association (AEA) in early January 20141. On the role of a central bank in a financial crisis, he said:

“For the U.S. and global economies, the most important event of the past eight years was, of course, the global financial crisis and the deep recession that it triggered. As I have observed on other occasions, the crisis bore a strong family resemblance to a classic financial panic, except that it took place in the complex environment of the 21st century global financial system. Likewise, the tools used to fight the panic, though adapted to the modern context, were analogous to those that would have been used a century ago, including liquidity provision by the central bank, liability guarantees, recapitalization, and the provision of assurances and information to the public.”

Furthermore:

“The Federal Reserve responded forcefully to the liquidity pressures during the crisis in a manner consistent with the lessons that central banks had learned from financial panics over more than 150 years and summarized in the writings of the 19th century British journalist Walter Bagehot: Lend early and freely to solvent institutions. However, the institutional context had changed substantially since Bagehot wrote. The panics of the 19th and early 20th centuries typically involved runs on commercial banks and other depository institutions. Prior to the recent crisis, in contrast, credit extension …….. Accordingly, to help calm the panic, the Federal Reserve provided liquidity not only to commercial banks, but also to other types of financial institutions such as investment banks and money market funds, as well as to key financial markets such as those for commercial paper and asset-backed securities. .Because funding markets are global in scope and U.S. borrowers depend importantly on foreign lenders, the Federal Reserve also approved currency swap agreements with 14 foreign central banks.

“Providing liquidity represented only the first step in stabilizing the financial system. Subsequent efforts focused on rebuilding the public’s confidence, notably including public guarantees of bank debt by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation and of money market funds by the Treasury Department, as well as the injection of public capital into banking institutions. The bank stress test that the Federal Reserve led in the spring of 2009, which included detailed public disclosure of information regarding the solvency of our largest banks, further buttressed confidence in the banking system.”

In the accompanying notes to his speech, the following explanations of shadow banking as well as the special arrangements made to boost liquidity were specified as follows:

“Shadow banking, as usually defined, comprises a diverse set of institutions and markets that, collectively, carry out traditional banking functions–but do so outside, or in ways only loosely linked to, the traditional system of regulated depository institutions. Examples of important components of the shadow banking system include securitization vehicles, asset-backed commercial paper conduits, money market funds, markets for repurchase agreements, investment banks, and nonbank mortgage companies.

“ Liquidity tools employed by the Federal Reserve that were closely tied to the central bank’s traditional role as lender of last resort involved the provision of short-term liquidity to depository and other financial institutions and included the traditional discount window, the Term Auction Facility (TAF), the Primary Dealer Credit Facility (PDCF), and the Term Securities Lending Facility (TSLF). A second set of tools involved the provision of liquidity directly to borrowers and investors in those credit markets key to households and businesses where the expanding crisis threatened to materially impede the availability of financing. The Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility (AMLF), the Commercial Paper Funding Facility (CPFF), the Money Market Investor Funding Facility (MMIFF), and the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF) fall into this category.”

The initial injections of liquidity by the Fed to deal with the crisis was followed by actions that did write a further new page to the central bankers’ play book. That is, in the form of very large and regular additional injections of additional cash into the financial system, made on the Fed’s own initiative, in the form of a massive bond and security buying programme, which accelerated in late 2011 and early 2013 (QE2 and QE3) that was undertaken not so much to shore up the financial system that had stabilized, but undertaken as conventional monetary policy to influence the state of the economy by managing key interest rates and especially mortgage rates.

Usually, monetary policy focuses on changes in short term interest rates, leaving long term interest rates and the slope of the yield curve to the market place. But in the US, the mortgage rate, so important for the US housing market, is a long term fixed rate of interest linked to long term interest rates and US Treasury Bond Yields. These long term fixed mortgage rates (30 year loans) available to homeowners are made possible only with the aid of government, in the form of the government sponsored mortgage lending bodies Fannie Mae and Freddy Mac, whose lending practices did so much to precipitate the housing boom and bust and were particularly in need of rescuing by the US Treasury. Their roles in the crisis do not feature in the Bernanke speech made to the AEA.

The state of the US housing market is a crucial ingredient for improving the state of US household balance sheets that are so necessary if households are to spend more in order that  that the US economy can recover from recession. Households account for over 70% of all final demands in the US and only when households lead can firms be expected to follow with their own spending plans. These household balance sheets had been devastated by the collapse in house prices, by 30% on average from the peak in 2006 to the trough in average house prices in 2011. It was this boom in house prices followed by a collapse in them that was the proximate cause of the financial crisis itself.

This bubble and bust, after all, happened on Bernanke’s watch as a governor and then as chairman of the Fed, for which the Fed does not take responsibility. A fuller explanation of the deeper causes of the GFC was offered by Bernanke in his speech to the AEA:

“The immediate trigger of the crisis, as you know, was a sharp decline in house prices, which reversed a previous run-up that had been fueled by irresponsible mortgage lending and securitization practices. Policymakers at the time, including myself, certainly appreciated that house prices might decline, although we disagreed about how much decline was likely; indeed, prices were already moving down when I took office in 2006. However, to a significant extent, our expectations about the possible macroeconomic effects of house price declines were shaped by the apparent analogy to the bursting of the dot-com bubble a few years earlier. That earlier bust also involved a large reduction in paper wealth but was followed by only a mild recession. In the event, of course, the bursting of the housing bubble helped trigger the most severe financial crisis since the Great Depression. It did so because, unlike the earlier decline in equity prices, it interacted with critical vulnerabilities in the financial system and in government regulation that allowed what were initially moderate aggregate losses to subprime mortgage holders to cascade through the financial system. In the private sector, key vulnerabilities included high levels of leverage, excessive dependence on unstable short-term funding, deficiencies in risk measurement and management, and the use of exotic financial instruments that redistributed risk in nontransparent ways. In the public sector, vulnerabilities included gaps in the regulatory structure that allowed some systemically important firms and markets to escape comprehensive supervision, failures of supervisors to effectively use their existing powers, and insufficient attention to threats to the stability of the system as a whole.”

The obvious question for critics of Bernanke is why the Fed itself did not do more to slow down the increases in the supply of credit from banks and the so called shadow banks? Perhaps the Fed could not do more, given its lack of adherence to money and credit supply targets and its heavy reliance on interest rates as its principal instrument of policy.

Given what happened in the housing price boom, it seems clear that policy determined interest rates should have been much higher to slow down the growth in credit. But it may also be argued that interest rates themselves are insufficient to moderate a credit cycle. This is an essentially monetarist point not addressed by Bernanke. In other words, to say there is more to monetary policy than interest rates. The supply of money and bank credit is deserving of control according to the monetarist critique. The Bernanke remedy for protecting the system against the prospect of a future financial crisis is predictably familiar: better regulation and more equity on the books of banks and other lenders. It may be argued that there will always be enough capital, regulated or not, in normal times, and too little in any financial crisis regardless of generally well funded financial institutions. Prevention of a financial crisis may prove impossible and the attempt to do so may be costly in terms of too little, rather than too much, lending and leverage in normal conditions (when lenders are appropriately default risk-conscious and do not make bad loans on a scale that makes for a credit and asset price bubble that ends in tears). The cure for a crisis should always be on hand and the Bernanke recipe will hopefully not be forgotten in the good times.

Any current concern about monetary aggregates would have to be on the liabilities side of the Fed balance sheet, conspicuous not so much for the volume of deposits held by the member commercial banks with the Fed, but with the historically unprecedented volume or ratio of deposits (cash) held by these banks with the Fed, in excess of their regulated cash reserve requirements. Also conspicuous is the lack of growth in bank lending to businesses – despite the abundance of cash on hand (see figures 2 and 3).

 

As Bernanke explained:

“To provide additional monetary policy accommodation despite the constraint imposed by the effective lower bound on interest rates, the Federal Reserve turned to two alternative tools: enhanced forward guidance regarding the likely path of the federal funds rate and large-scale purchases of longer-term securities for the Federal Reserve’s portfolio. Other major central banks have responded to developments since 2008 in roughly similar ways. For example, the Bank of England and the Bank of Japan have employed detailed forward guidance and conducted large-scale asset purchases, while the European Central Bank has moved to reduce the perceived risk of sovereign debt, provided banks with substantial liquidity, and offered qualitative guidance regarding the future path of interest rates.”

The use of forward guidance to help the market place forecast the path of interest rates more accurately, so reducing uncertainties in the market place leading hopefully to better financial decisions, predates the Bernanke chairmanship of the Fed. However, he should be credited with taking the Fed to new levels of transparency and much improved communication with both the marketplace and the politicians. In Bernanke’s words:

“The crisis and its aftermath, however, raised the need for communication and explanation by the Federal Reserve to a new level. We took extraordinary measures to meet extraordinary economic challenges, and we had to explain those measures to earn the public’s support and confidence. Talking only to the Congress and to market participants would not have been enough. The effort to inform the public engaged the whole institution, including both Board members and the staff. As Chairman, I did my part, by appearing on television programs, holding town halls, taking student questions at universities, and visiting a military base to talk to soldiers and their families. The Federal Reserve Banks also played key roles in providing public information in their Districts, through programs, publications, speeches, and other media.

The crisis has passed, but I think the Fed’s need to educate and explain will only grow.”

Historically US banks held minimum excess cash reserves, meeting any demand for cash by borrowing reserves in the Federal Funds market (the interbank market for cash), so making the Fed Funds rate the key money market rate and the instrument of Fed monetary policy. Holding idle cash is not usually profitable banking – but it has become so to an extraordinary degree. Furthermore, the large volume of excess reserves means that short term interest rates fall to zero from which they cannot fall any further. The reason they have remained above zero is that the Fed has been willing to reward the banks for their excess reserves by offering 0.25% p.a on their deposits with the Fed.

Every purchase of bonds or mortgage backed securities made by the Fed in its asset purchase programme must end up on the books of a bank as a deposit with the Fed. But before the extra phases of QE, the banks would make every effort to put their cash to work earning interest rather than holding them largely idle (as they are now doing). But it would appear that the Fed expects the demand for excess cash to remain a permanent feature of the financial landscape and can cope accordingly.

According to Bernanke:

“Large-scale asset purchases have increased the size of our balance sheet and created substantial excess reserves in the banking system. Under the operating procedures used prior to the crisis, the presence of large quantities of excess reserves likely would have impeded the FOMC’s ability to raise short-term nominal interest rates when appropriate. However, the Federal Reserve now has effective tools to normalize the stance of policy when conditions warrant, without reliance on asset sales. The interest rate on excess reserves can be raised, which will put upward pressure on short-term rates; in addition, the Federal Reserve will be able to employ other tools, such as fixed-rate overnight reverse repurchase agreements, term deposits, or term repurchase agreements, to drain bank reserves and tighten its control over money market rates if this proves necessary. As a result, at the appropriate time, the FOMC will be able to return to conducting monetary policy primarily through adjustments in the short-term policy rate. It is possible, however, that some specific aspects of the Federal Reserve’s operating framework will change; the Committee will be considering this question in the future, taking into account what it learned from its experience with an expanded balance sheet and new tools for managing interest rates.”

It seems clear that the market is not frightened by the prospect that abundant supplies of cash will in turn lead to more inflation as the cash is lent and spent, as monetary history foretells. The market clearly believes in the capacity of the Fed to remove the proverbial punchbowl before the party gets going. Judged by the difference between yields on vanilla Treasury bonds and their inflation protected alternatives, inflation of no more than 2% a year is expected in the US over the next 20 years. According to Bernanke, who is much more concerned with the dangers of deflation, arguing that inflation of less than 2% should be regarded as deflation (given the hard to measure improvements in the quality of goods and services). Therefore if inflation is less than 2% this becomes an argument for more, rather than less, accommodative monetary policy by the Fed.

The market clearly finds the Bernanke arguments and guidance highly convincing. These expectations are a measure of Bernanke’s success as a central banker. He has surely helped save the financial system from a potential disaster and has done so without adding to fears of inflation.

The US economy has not however enjoyed the strong recovery that usually follows a recession. Bernanke has some explanation for this tepid growth:

“In retrospect, at least, many of the factors that held back the recovery can be identified. Some of these factors were difficult or impossible to anticipate, such as the resurgence in financial volatility associated with the European sovereign debt and banking crisis and the economic effects of natural disasters in Japan and elsewhere. Other factors were more predictable; in particular, we appreciated early on, though perhaps to a lesser extent than we might have, that the boom and bust left severe imbalances that would take time to work off. As Carmen Reinhart and Ken Rogoff noted in their prescient research, economic activity following financial crises tends to be anemic, especially when the preceding economic expansion was accompanied by rapid growth in credit and real estate prices.16 Weak recoveries from financial crises reflect, in part, the process of deleveraging and balance sheet repair: Households pull back on spending to recoup lost wealth and reduce debt burdens, while financial institutions restrict credit to restore capital ratios and reduce the riskiness of their portfolios. In addition to these financial factors, the weakness of the recovery reflects the overbuilding of housing (and, to some extent, commercial real estate) prior to the crisis, together with tight mortgage credit; indeed, recent activity in these areas is especially tepid in comparison to the rapid gains in construction more typically seen in recoveries.”

He also blames the slow recovery on the unintended consequence of unplanned government fiscal austerity:

“To this list of reasons for the slow recovery–the effects of the financial crisis, problems in the housing and mortgage markets, weaker-than-expected productivity growth, and events in Europe and elsewhere–I would add one more significant factor– – 18 – Since that time, however, federal fiscal policy has turned quite restrictive; according to the Congressional Budget Office, tax increases and spending cuts likely lowered output growth in 2013 by as much as 1-1/2 percentage points. In addition, throughout much of the recovery, state and local government budgets have been highly contractionary, reflecting their adjustment to sharply declining tax revenues. To illustrate the extent of fiscal tightness, at the current point in the recovery from the 2001 recession, employment at all levels of government had increased by nearly 600,000 workers; in contrast, in the current recovery, government employment has declined by more than 700,000 jobs, a net difference of more than 1.3 million jobs. There have been corresponding cuts in government investment, in infrastructure for example, as well as increases in taxes and reductions in transfers.

“Although long-term fiscal sustainability is a critical objective, excessively tight near-term fiscal policies have likely been counterproductive. Most importantly, with fiscal and monetary policy working in opposite directions, the recovery is weaker than it otherwise would be. But the current policy mix is particularly problematic when interest rates are very low, as is the case today. Monetary policy has less room to maneuver when interest rates are close to zero, while expansionary fiscal policy is likely both more effective and less costly in terms of increased debt burden when interest rates are pinned at low levels. A more balanced policy mix might also avoid some of the costs of very low interest rates, such as potential risks to financial stability, without sacrificing jobs and growth.”

Bernanke then went on to paint an optimistic picture of the US economy:

“I have discussed the factors that have held back the recovery, not only to better understand the recent past but also to think about the economy’s prospects. The encouraging news is that the headwinds I have mentioned may now be abating. Near-term fiscal policy at the federal level remains restrictive, but the degree of restraint on economic growth seems likely to lessen somewhat in 2014 and even more so in 2015; meanwhile, the budgetary situations of state and local governments have improved, reducing the need for further sharp cuts. The aftereffects of the housing bust also appear to have waned. For example, notwithstanding the effects of somewhat higher mortgage rates, house prices have rebounded, with one consequence being that the number of homeowners with “underwater” mortgages has dropped significantly, as have foreclosures and mortgage delinquencies. Household balance sheets have strengthened considerably, with wealth and income rising and the household debt-service burden at its lowest level in decades. Partly as a result of households’ improved finances, lending standards to households are showing signs of easing, though potential mortgage borrowers still face impediments. Businesses, especially larger ones, are also in good financial shape. The combination of financial healing, greater balance in the housing market, less fiscal restraint, and, of course, continued monetary policy accommodation bodes well for U.S. economic growth in coming quarters. But, of course, if the experience of the past few years teaches us anything, it is that we should be cautious in our forecasts.”

It can be argued by his critics that the Bernanke innovations have been part of the problem rather than the solution. It would be very hard to argue that injecting liquidity and capital into the financial system to avert an incipient financial crisis in 2008-09 was the wrong thing to do. But it may yet be asked, then, if QE2 and QE3 were also necessary? Would not a sooner return to monetary normality have been confidence boosting, rather than undermining, business confidence, which is essential to any sustained recovery? Further bouts of QE have led to large additions to the excess cash held by banks, rather than additional lending undertaken by them that would have helped the economy along. Would the banks and the US corporations have put more of their strong balance sheets to work to help the economy along had monetary policy been less innovative, or at least had QE not been advanced as strongly as it was? Growth in bank credit and money supply (M2) has slowed down rather than picked up in recent years, despite the creation of so much more base money (see the figure on bank lending). That the banks have been able to earn 0.25% on their vast cash balances has surely encouraged them to hold rather than lend out their cash.

Furthermore, while fiscal policy could have been less restrictive in the short run, would any political failure to implement a modest degree of austerity at Federal and State level, not have made households even more anxious about their economic futures and the tax burdens accompanying them, leading to still less private spending?

The performance of the US economy over the next few years will be the test of the Bernanke years. If the US economy regains momentum without inflation, the Bernanke innovations will have proved their worth. They would then provide the concrete evidence that it is possible to create money, à outrance, and then take away the juice when that becomes necessary. Tapering of QE, the initial thought of which that so disturbed the markets in May 2013, is but a first tentative step to the actual withdrawal of cash from the system and the shrinking of the Fed balance sheet. The monetary experiment, conducted with deep knowledge of monetary history and theory that fortunately characterised the Bernanke years, remains an experiment. We must hope for the sake of continued economic progress both in the US and elsewhere that it proves a highly successful experiment.

1The Federal Reserve: Looking Back, Looking Forward, Remarks by Ben S. Bernanke, Chairman Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System at
Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
3 January 2014
Source: Federal Reserve System of the United States, Speeches of Governors. All quotations referred to are taken from the published version of this speech.

Economic reality and the MPC – coming together?

The first and second meetings of the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) of the Reserve Bank in 2014 have come and gone and been accompanied by very different reactions in the money market.

The first meeting on 29 January produced a significant interest rate surprise on the upside when the MPC decided to raise its key repo rate by 50bps. The second meeting on 27 March produced a much smaller surprise in the other direction. Note in the chart below that the first upside interest rate surprise in January 2014 was associated with a significantly weaker rand while the surprising downside move in short term interest rates in March was accompanied by a stronger rand. Short term rates are represented in the figure by the Johannesburg interbank rate (Jibar) expected in three months – that is the forward rate of interest implicit in the relationship between the three month and six month JIBAR rate. Changes in this rate indicate interest rate surprises. Hence the inflation outlook deteriorated as interest rates moved higher and improved as interest rates were kept on hold.

This inconsistent and essentially unpredictable relationship between movements in SA interest rates and the rand is clearly coincidental – it is not a causal relationship because the value of the rand is determined by global or (more particularly) emerging market economic forces rather than domestic policy decisions. As we show below, where emerging market equities go, the rand follows. And emerging equity and bond markets are led by global risk appetite. The more inclined global investors are to take on more risk, the better emerging market equities and bonds perform, including those listed on the JSE. The behaviour of SA stocks and bonds and the exchange value of the rand is highly consistent with that of emerging markets genrally as we show in the chart below. The rand follows the Emerging Market Equity Index (MSCI EM) as does the JSE All Share Index (both in US dollars) while both the rand and the JSE respond to the spread between RSA and US Treasury 10 year bond yields that can be regarded as a measure of SA specific exchange rate risk. The wider the spread the more exchange rate weakness expected.

But what does this all mean for monetary policy in SA and for the direction of short term interest rates? As we are all well aware Reserve Bank interest rate settings are meant to hold inflation within its target band of three to six per cent per annum. But inflation takes its cue mostly from the direction of the rand, which is beyond any predictable influence of interest rates – as has been demonstrated once more.

And so the Reserve Bank remains essentially powerless to manage inflation in the face of exchange rate shocks (over which it has no obvious or predictable influence). Interest rates can influence spending in SA, causing the economy to grow faster or slower without necessarily influencing the direction of prices. In other words inflation can rise, as it has done recently, even though the economy has operated well below its potential and will continue to do so. Therefore higher interest rates can  slow the economy down further without causing inflation to fall. This is a painful dilemma of which the MPC seems only too well aware. To quote its statement of 27 March:

“The Monetary Policy Committee is acutely aware of the policy dilemma of rising inflation pressures in a subdued economic growth environment.

“The main upside risk to the forecast continues to come from the exchange rate, which, despite the recent relative stability, remains vulnerable to global rebalancing. The expected normalisation of monetary policy in advanced economies is unlikely to be linear or smooth, and the timing and pace is uncertain.

“The rand is also vulnerable to domestic idiosyncratic factors, including protracted work stoppages, electricity supply constraints, and the slow adjustment of the current account deficit. Pass-through from the exchange rate to prices has been relatively muted to date but there is some evidence that it is accelerating. However, the forecast already incorporates a higher pass-through than has been experienced up to now.

“At the same time, the domestic economic outlook remains fragile, with the risks assessed to be on the downside. Demand pressures remain benign as consumption expenditure continues to slow amid weakening credit extension to households and high levels of household indebtedness. The upward trend in the core inflation forecast is assessed to reflect exchange rate pressures rather than underlying demand pressures.”

So then how should the MPC respond to exchange rate-driven price increases? The obvious answer would appear to be to accept the limitations of inflation targeting in the absence of any predictable reaction of exchange rates to interest rate settings. That is to ignore completely the exchange rate shock effect on inflation and focus on domestic forces that influence the inflation rate: lowering rates when the economy is operating below potential and raising them when spending (led by money and credit growth) is growing so rapidly as to add to inflationary pressures. And to explain very clearly why it would be acting this way.

But this unfortunately is not the way the MPC is still inclined to think. It worries about the inflationary effect of inflationary expectations. To quote its recent statement again:

“Given the lags with which monetary policy operates, the MPC will continue to focus on the medium term inflation trajectory. The committee is aware that too slow a pace of tightening could undermine inflation expectations and may require more aggressive tightening in the future. Consistent with our mandate, a fine balance is required to ensure that inflation is contained while minimising the cost to output”.

The MPC would be well advised to accept another bit of SA economic reality, which is that not only does the exchange rate lead inflation, but inflation itself leads inflation expectations – not the other other way round. There is no evidence that inflationary expectations lead inflation higher or lower. More SA inflation leads to more inflation expected though, as the MPC is well aware, inflation expected has remained remarkably constant over the years: around six per cent per annum that is the upper end of the inflation target band.

The MPC did the right thing this time round not to raise its repo rate. It made a mistake to raise its repo rate at the January meeting. The money market made the mistake of immediately anticipating a further 200bp increase in interest rates by January 2015. The Governor has done very good work guiding the market away from such interest rate expectations that, if realised, would be even more costly to the economy. The money market now expects only a 100bp increase in short term rates by early next year. The market may again be very wrong about this, dependent as the direction of inflation and interest rates are on the behaviour of the rand over the next 12 months. But even good news for the exchange rate will still leave monetary policy in SA on a fundamentally wrong tack. The interest rate cycle in SA, as in any normal economic state of affairs, should be led by the state of the domestic economy, not by the direction of unpredictable global capital.

Monetary policy: The limits to inflation targeting

Is SA monetary policy accommodative? It all depends on whose inflation and whose interest rates you have in mind

We are told by the Reserve Bank that monetary policy in SA is “accommodative” because interest rates are below the rate of inflation. That is because real interest rates are negative. But whose interest rates and whose inflation rates can the Reserve Bank be referring to? From the perspective of lenders the interest paid on savings accounts in the banks are not keeping up with inflation – and more so if tax has to be paid on interest income. Low real interest rates are tough on savers, but, for a good reason, borrowers may be unable to pay any more for the use of their savings.

But from the perspective of business borrowers, especially small businesses still able to borrow from their banks at prime plus something over 9%, finance may in reality be very expensive. The presumption of negative real interest rates is that businesses will be able to increase the prices they charge their customers at more than the 9% per annum they pay in interest. If this were the case, simply financing a warehouse of non-perishable goods that increase in value by more than the costs of finance (after taxes) becomes a no-brainer of a profitable business decision. This would presumably make monetary policy accommodative and encourage business.

But is this currently the case for many businesses serving the domestic market? Do they currently have the power to price their goods or services ahead of the rate of inflation that was 5.4% in December 2013?

The weakened state of demand for goods and services may prevent this as the more detailed inflation statistics bear out. The headline inflation rate is the weighted average of the prices of goods and services consumed by the mythical average SA household, some of which have risen by much more than the average and others by much less. It is administered prices, those charged by municipalities for water and electricity etc and those subject to additional excise duties, for example alcoholic beverages (up 7.2% on average with beer up 9.2% on December a year before), that have been making the inflation running . Administered prices were up nearly 8% on a year before in December 2013.

By contrast, the price of clothing and footwear is estimated to have increased by a mere 3.6% and 3% respectively. The food basket itself was also only 3% up, believe it or not. The farmers, food retailers and manufacturers will know all about their pricing power and the pressure on their sales volumes and profit margins.

It is clear that rising prices in SA have very little to do with any strong demands being registered by consumers. As is well recognized, SA households are under increasing budget pressures from higher prices and taxes imposed upon them. And, most relevant, they are suffering from a lack of pricing power in the most important market for their services, in the market for their labour services.

By recent accounts from Adcorp the rate of dismissal from private sector jobs is accelerating and workers are much less mobile than usual. They are therefore presumably somewhat fearfully holding onto the jobs they have, rather than moving to better paid ones. This is not an environment likely to encourage growth in spending, despite interest rates in the money market being below the headline inflation rate.

In fact monetary policy is doing very little to encourage domestic spending and, indeed, with the recent increase in benchmark short rates, has become less so. Even less demand side pressure on spending can be expected as prices continue to rise, driven especially by a weaker rand over which domestic interest rates have little or no influence.

The fact that the SA economy is as weak as it is, indicates quite clearly that interest rates should have been significantly lower than they have been, and that they should be falling, rather than rising, given the deteriorating state of the economy. Furthermore, targeting inflation when prices are rising for supply side (exchange rate shocks, drought and taxes) rather than demand side reasons makes little economic sense. Inflation targeting in SA can only makes good sense when the exchange rate itself responds predictably to interests rate settings. The rand over much of the past 12 years or so has not behaved anything like this.

Aiming for low inflation is good monetary policy. Trying to meet inflation targets is proving again to mean very poor monetary policy in S.A.

The Hard Number Index: Foot off the accelerator

Hard numbers for January 2014 in the form of vehicle sales and notes in circulation are now available. We combine them to form our Hard Number Index (HNI) – a useful indicator of the state of the SA economy because it is so up to date.

The indication from the HNI is that while the economy is maintaining its forward momentum (numbers above 100 indicate growth) the pace of growth is slowing down and is forecast to slow further in the months ahead. This lower absolute number for the HNI in January 2014 is the first decline in the HNI registered since the economy escaped from the recession of 2008-09, when the HNI as may be seen turned briefly below the 100 level.

The turning points in the HNI anticipate those of the Reserve Bank Coinciding Business Cycle Indicator consistently well, as we also show. However this business cycle indicator has only been updated to October 2013 which is a long time ago in the business of economic analysis and forecasting. It will not come as much of a surprise to observers that the pace of domestic spending in SA slowed down in January. Higher short term interest rates imposed by the Reserve Bank in late January 2014 will do nothing to encourage spending growth that at best was stalling in the final quarter of 2013.

 

It was the slowdown in the growth in the supply and demand for cash (adjusted for inflation) in January 2014 that dragged the HNI lower. The real money base growth cycle peaked in 2011 and has been on a more or less consistently lower trajectory since then. The forecast is for a further decline in this growth rate.

 

By contrast, unit vehicle sales in January 2014 held up well. On a seasonally adjusted basis unit sales in January 2014 were about 1000 units higher than in December 2013, that in turn, on a seasonally adjusted basis, were well up on November 2013 sales.

For the motor dealers, December and January are both usually below average months for selling new vehicles. The current level of sales would translate into an annual rate of sales of about 650 000 units this time next year, which would be little changed from the pace of sales in 2013. However some preemptive buying ahead of exchange rate forced increases in list prices may well have provided a temporary boost to new unit sales in December and January. A combination of a weaker rand and higher financing costs does not bode well for the new vehicle market in SA.

For motor and component manufacturers, the profit opportunity must be in export markets where prices are set presumably in foreign currencies – trade unions permitting. The opportunity for SA to lift growth rates from the currently unsatisfactory pace, must lie with increases in export volumes. The weak real rand/US dollar rate, currently about 17% below its purchasing power equivalent value compared to its 1995 value, offers the opportunity for SA producers to take full advantage of higher operating profit margins to increase export volumes and rand revenues significantly. It is up to SA management and workers to seize the opportunity to share in the operating surpluses that a weak real rand makes possible.